1986
DOI: 10.2307/1960862
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Organizing Groups for Collective Action

Abstract: How can the beneficiaries of collective action be persuaded to contribute the resources (time, energy, money) necessary for the effort to succeed? Rational and selfish players will recognize they can free ride on the successful contributions of others. If the effort is not successful, they will lose a contribution—and be “suckered.” Other than relying on altruism, organizers of the group effort can modify incentives so that players are more prepared to contribute. Laboratory experiments offer one way of assess… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

6
99
0
2

Year Published

1998
1998
2014
2014

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 142 publications
(107 citation statements)
references
References 16 publications
6
99
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…We demonstrate that both factors contributed to the poor showing of stable coalitions with memberfinanced enforcement. Like other authors (Van de Kragt et al 1983;Dawes et al 1986;Suleimen and Rapoport 1992;Rapoport and Suleimen 1993;Cadsby and Maynes 1999) we find that increasing the participation threshold lowered the average provision of a public good because coalitions formed less frequently. Moreover, even though we structured the compliance incentives so that each member of a coalition had the financial motivation to comply, a significant number did not.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 86%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…We demonstrate that both factors contributed to the poor showing of stable coalitions with memberfinanced enforcement. Like other authors (Van de Kragt et al 1983;Dawes et al 1986;Suleimen and Rapoport 1992;Rapoport and Suleimen 1993;Cadsby and Maynes 1999) we find that increasing the participation threshold lowered the average provision of a public good because coalitions formed less frequently. Moreover, even though we structured the compliance incentives so that each member of a coalition had the financial motivation to comply, a significant number did not.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 86%
“…Thus, we can explain the poor performance of the costly enforcement treatment by examining the relative importance of these effects. Kragt et al 1983;Dawes et al 1986;Isaac et al 1989;Rapoport and Eshed-Levy 1989;Erev and Rapoport 1990;Suleimen and Rapoport 1992;Rapoport and Suleimen 1993;Mysker et al 1996;Marks and Croson 1998;Marks and Croson 1999). A handful of other studies have found results that do not fall into the 50 -70% participation range, including Cadsby and Maynes (1999) who found that the public good is provided in only 26% of pooled trials and Bagnoli and Mckee (1991) who found that the public good was provided in 83% of all trials.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The dominant strategy is a zero contribution no matter what others do. An oft-replicated finding, however, is that the willingness of subjects to contribute to the provision of a public good is strongly correlated with their expectations of the behavior of others (Dawes, McTavish, and Shaklee, 1977;Dawes, Orbell, and van de Kragt, 1986;Orbell and Dawes, 1991;Brandts andSchram, 1995: Croson, 1998). In a provision point experiment, for example, all those who contributed sufficient funds to produce the benefit predicted that sufficient funds would be provided by others to make their own contribution superfluous (Messick, 1999).…”
Section: Elinor Ostrommentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Behavioural research using game theoretic models show that co-operative behaviour is the outcome when realistic options are allowed such as continuous communication among players and retaliation toward free riders. As summarised by Gintis (2000) games such as The Ultimatum Game (Güth et al 1982), The Public Goods Game (Isaac et al 1994), and the Public Goods Game with Retaliation (Dawes et al 1986) consistently show that co-operative, group-beneficial behaviour is pervasive in human groups. Boyd and Richerson (1992) argue persuasively that when retaliation (punishment for anti-social behaviour) is allowed almost any conceivable behaviour may evolve in large groups.…”
Section: Group Selectionmentioning
confidence: 99%