1992
DOI: 10.1111/j.1468-0289.1992.tb01313.x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Output growth and the British industrial revolution: a restatement of the Crafts-Harley view

Abstract: n the early 1980s we published revised estimates of aggregate economic I performance during the British industrial revolution which have stimulated reappraisal of the beginnings of modern economic growth.2 These new estimates have led most scholars to abandon the previous orthodoxy which had been based on the pioneering work of Deane and Cole.3 We have subsequently explored further aspects of the industrial revolution using our 1982/3 estimates of the rate of growth as acceptable best g~e s s e s .~ Recently, … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

11
105
1

Year Published

2000
2000
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
4
3
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 171 publications
(117 citation statements)
references
References 14 publications
11
105
1
Order By: Relevance
“…So much progress had been made by 1700 that the shift of labour from agriculture to industry during the eighteenth century was smaller than that proposed by Crafts and Harley, thereby reinstating industry as the sector with the fastest labour productivity growth during the classic Industrial Revolution period. Although there was also substantial agricultural labour productivity growth between 1700 and 1851, it was at a slower pace than in industry, thus reversing the most paradoxical finding of Crafts and Harley (1992). Yet while these findings reconcile the output estimates of Crafts and Harley with traditional views of an industrially dynamic Industrial Revolution they challenge those of Clark (2012), who argues for little or no trend growth in per capita incomes before 1800 and a relatively late final shift of labour out of agriculture.…”
Section: Accepted M Manuscriptcontrasting
confidence: 49%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…So much progress had been made by 1700 that the shift of labour from agriculture to industry during the eighteenth century was smaller than that proposed by Crafts and Harley, thereby reinstating industry as the sector with the fastest labour productivity growth during the classic Industrial Revolution period. Although there was also substantial agricultural labour productivity growth between 1700 and 1851, it was at a slower pace than in industry, thus reversing the most paradoxical finding of Crafts and Harley (1992). Yet while these findings reconcile the output estimates of Crafts and Harley with traditional views of an industrially dynamic Industrial Revolution they challenge those of Clark (2012), who argues for little or no trend growth in per capita incomes before 1800 and a relatively late final shift of labour out of agriculture.…”
Section: Accepted M Manuscriptcontrasting
confidence: 49%
“…This is in line with the recent findings of Shaw-Taylor (2009a). Since post-1700 growth rates of output by sector and in the aggregate economy remain broadly as suggested by Crafts and Harley (1992), this means that labour productivity growth was faster in industry and slower in agriculture.…”
Section: Concluding Commentsmentioning
confidence: 97%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Galor and Moav (2002) propose that during the epoch of Malthusian stagnation that characterized most of human existence, individuals with a higher valuation for offspring quality gained an evolutionary advantage and their representation in the population gradually increased. The agricultural revolution facilitated the division of labor and fostered trade relationships across individuals and communities, 68 This mechanism was outlined by Galor and Weil (1999) and was examined in different settings by Erlich and Lui (1991), and Hazan and Zoabi (2004). It should be noted, however, that as argued by Moav (2005), the rise in the potential return to investment in child quality due to the prolongation of the productive life is not as straightforward as it may appear.…”
Section: Natural Selection and The Evolution Of Preference For Offsprmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…That this period should be subject to closer scrutiny follows from the revised assessments of historians of economic growth, who argue that the Industrial Revolution can no longer be regarded "as the beginnings of growth altogether but as the time at which technology assumed an everincreasing weight in the generation of growth" (Mokyr (2005)) and that the "accumulated evidence for an earlier increase in per capita income in northwestern Europe paired with a major refinement of material life casts serious doubt on the orthodoxy that the Industrial Revolution was the actual starting point for long-term economic growth" (de Vries, 2008, p.6). 9 Once the roots of long-term growth are seen to be planted in an era earlier than has traditionally been accepted, the question that immediately arises is the one concerning Crafts and Harley (1992), Crafts (1985), Feinstein (1998), Mokyr (2004), and Williamson (1984).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%