2015
DOI: 10.1111/risa.12511
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Overcoming Learning Aversion in Evaluating and Managing Uncertain Risks

Abstract: Decision biases can distort cost-benefit evaluations of uncertain risks, leading to risk management policy decisions with predictably high retrospective regret. We argue that well-documented decision biases encourage learning aversion, or predictably suboptimal learning and premature decision making in the face of high uncertainty about the costs, risks, and benefits of proposed changes. Biases such as narrow framing, overconfidence, confirmation bias, optimism bias, ambiguity aversion, and hyperbolic discount… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
5
0

Year Published

2016
2016
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
3
1

Relationship

0
4

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 4 publications
(5 citation statements)
references
References 61 publications
0
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…For example, finding that investments in a costly course of action have yielded lower-than-expected returns may provoke those who originally chose it to escalate their commitment to it (Molden & Hui, 2011; Schultze et al, 2012). Possible psychological and political explanations for escalating commitment range from loss aversion to seeking to manage the impressions of others, but clearly such resistance to modifying or abandoning previous choices in light of experience inhibits effective learning (Cox, 2015; Tetlock & Gardner, 2015). In business as well as government, data needed to evaluate and compare actual to predicted performance of a policy are often not even collected, or are ignored or misinterpreted if they are collected (Russo & Schoemaker, 1989).…”
Section: Discussion: Implications Of Advances In Rational-comprehensimentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…For example, finding that investments in a costly course of action have yielded lower-than-expected returns may provoke those who originally chose it to escalate their commitment to it (Molden & Hui, 2011; Schultze et al, 2012). Possible psychological and political explanations for escalating commitment range from loss aversion to seeking to manage the impressions of others, but clearly such resistance to modifying or abandoning previous choices in light of experience inhibits effective learning (Cox, 2015; Tetlock & Gardner, 2015). In business as well as government, data needed to evaluate and compare actual to predicted performance of a policy are often not even collected, or are ignored or misinterpreted if they are collected (Russo & Schoemaker, 1989).…”
Section: Discussion: Implications Of Advances In Rational-comprehensimentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Reasons abound in individual and group psychology for keeping those who make decisions about policy adjustments (analogous to “actors” in actor-critic RL algorithms) separate from those who evaluate the performance of the policies and provide feedback and suggestions for improving them (the “critics”). Among these reasons are confirmation bias, motivated reasoning, groupthink, and other heuristics and biases (Cox, 2015). RL suggests an additional reason, rooted in statistics: in deep learning RL algorithms, training one network to decide what to do next and a separate one to evaluate how well it is working has been found to prevent overly optimistic assessments of policy performance due to overfitting, i.e., using the same data to both select estimated value-maximizing actions and estimate the values from taking those actions (van Hesselt et al, 2015).…”
Section: Discussion: Implications Of Advances In Rational-comprehensimentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Needless to say, the findings presented in this paper require further investigation, both within the same contexts (e.g., by allowing the degree of risk aversion to be updated according to experience, or the degree of regret to differ from the degree of rejoice) and in alternative contexts. For example, research should consider unknown probability distributions (Palley and Kremer, 2014), unobserved outcomes of foregone alternatives, the additional possibility of choosing actions for exploration (Gonzalez, 2013;Cox, 2015), and learning from other people's experience.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Needless to say, the findings presented in this paper require further investigation in alternative contexts. For example, research should consider scenarios with unknown probability distributions (Palley & Kremer, 2014), unobserved outcomes of alternatives that were not chosen (Mengel & Rivas, 2012), the additional possibility of choosing actions for exploration (Cox, 2015;Gonzalez, 2013), and learning from other people's experience (Meub & Proeger, 2017).…”
Section: Assumptions and Future Development Of The Approachmentioning
confidence: 99%