1965
DOI: 10.1037/h0022125
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Overconfidence in case-study judgments.

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

21
367
1
28

Year Published

1996
1996
2016
2016

Publication Types

Select...
6
1
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 844 publications
(417 citation statements)
references
References 13 publications
21
367
1
28
Order By: Relevance
“…It is remarkable because the two alternatives are so salient. On the one hand, there are circumstances in which new information increases confidence more than accuracy, exacerbating overconfidence (Hall et al 2007, Heath and Gonzalez 1995, Oskamp 1965. On the other hand, there are other circumstances in which increasing expertise can increase accuracy faster than confidence, reducing overconfidence (Koriat et al 2002).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 98%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…It is remarkable because the two alternatives are so salient. On the one hand, there are circumstances in which new information increases confidence more than accuracy, exacerbating overconfidence (Hall et al 2007, Heath and Gonzalez 1995, Oskamp 1965. On the other hand, there are other circumstances in which increasing expertise can increase accuracy faster than confidence, reducing overconfidence (Koriat et al 2002).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…However, some kinds of information increase confidence without increasing accuracy, and vice versa, even for experts (Griffin and Tversky 1992). As Oskamp (1965) memorably demonstrated, psychologists who learned more details of patients' life histories grew more confident in their diagnoses, without commensurate increases in accuracy. If additional information enhances confidence more than accuracy, it could drive up overconfidence (Deaves et al 2010).…”
Section: Effects Over Timementioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…On the other hand, if the trader is not rational, then his or her subjective belief is parameterized by K j = K , where K is a nonnegative misperception parameter such that K = 1. Furthermore, a nonrational trader is overconfident if his or her subjective distribution is too tight, i.e., 0 ≤ K < 1, or underconfident if it is too loose, i.e., K > 1 (Oskamp (1965), Alpert and Raiffa (1959), Einhorn and Hogarth (1978)). …”
Section: Overconfidence In a Pairwise Contestmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Individuals often demonstrate inaccurate assessments of their environments, including their own abilities, payoffs, and probabilistic assessments. For example, people are frequently overconfident, with voluminous evidence suggesting that the ranks of the overconfident include judges (Guthrie, Rachlinski and Wistrich, 2001), psychologists (Oskamp, 1965), physicians (Christensen-Szalanski and Bushyhead, 1981), engineers (Kidd, 1970), entrepreneurs (Camerer and Lovallo, 1999;Cooper et al, 1988), negotiators (Babcock and Loewenstein, 1997), securities analysts (Froot and Frankel, 1989;De Bondt and Thaler, 1985), and managers (Russo and Schoemaker, 1992). In many experiments, subjects sacrifice personal payoffs to reward or punish others, or for purely altruistic reasons.Evidence also suggests that the nature of these departures may vary with the context or nature of interaction.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%