2003
DOI: 10.1007/s00355-003-0198-x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Political culture and monopoly price determination

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1
1

Citation Types

0
15
0

Year Published

2005
2005
2007
2007

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

3
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 31 publications
(15 citation statements)
references
References 48 publications
0
15
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Suppose that a status-quo policy, I s , is challenged by one interest group and defended by another group. This policy can be the price of a regulated monopoly, Baik (1999), Epstein and Nitzan (2003), the degree of restriction of bank branching, Kroszner and Strahan (1999), or the determination of minimum wage, Grossman and Helpman (2001, Chapter 8.2). The defender of the status-quo policy (henceforth, interest group d) prefers the status-quo policy I s to any alternative policy.…”
Section: The Public-policy Gamementioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Suppose that a status-quo policy, I s , is challenged by one interest group and defended by another group. This policy can be the price of a regulated monopoly, Baik (1999), Epstein and Nitzan (2003), the degree of restriction of bank branching, Kroszner and Strahan (1999), or the determination of minimum wage, Grossman and Helpman (2001, Chapter 8.2). The defender of the status-quo policy (henceforth, interest group d) prefers the status-quo policy I s to any alternative policy.…”
Section: The Public-policy Gamementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Governments determine quotas that may well exceed the quota preferred by the capital owner who takes part in the political contest over the quota, and this quota can be lower than his optimal amount of migrants in a situation where the quota is certainly approved (there is no political contest on the determination of the quota), see for example Boeri, Hanson and McCormick (2002). The price of a regulated monopoly, Baik (1999), Epstein and Nitzan (2003), or the degree of restriction of bank branching, Kroszner and Strahan (1999), may well be other examples where the proposed policy is more extreme than the policy that would have been proposed by the relevant interest groups.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 96%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The studies concerned with the effect of asymmetry have focused on prize, value or stake asymmetry (Epstein and Nitzan, 2004, 2003Hillman and Riley, 1989;Hurley, 1998;Konrad and Schlesinger, 1997;Nti, 1999Nti, , 1997Stein, 2002), asymmetric lobbying capabilities (Baik, 1999(Baik, , 1994Gradstein, 1995;Keem, 1998;Kohli and Singh, 1999;Leininger, 1993;Singh and Wittman, 2001;Stein, 2002), asymmetric information (Hurley, 1998;Hurley andShogren, 1998a, 1998b;Wärneryd, 2003), asymmetric constrained budgets Gale, 1998, 1997) and asymmetric sharing rules within groups competing on a collective rent (Davis and Reilly, 1999;Nitzan, 1991). The studies concerned with the effect of uncertainty have focused on uncertainty regarding the awarded prize (Chung, 1999), uncertainty regarding the existence of opposition (Cairns and Long, 1991;Ellingsen, 1991;Epstein and Nitzan, 2003) and uncertainty regarding the mere award of the contestable rent (Kahana and Nitzan, 1999). denote by d. We assume that they share the common prior that d is equally likely to be one bureaucrat or the other.…”
Section: Political Powermentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Relative to this definition of mercantilism, we label the modern mercantilism of Asian economies "implicit." A significant academic literature identifies the mercantile quality of the modern Asian state (Epstein and Nitzan, 2002;Landa, 1994). There is also a large technical literature on institutional structure and trade performance (notably Hillman, 1989), as well as a literature concerning specifically the structure and performance of Asian neo-mercantile states (Dhar and Panagariya, 1999).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%