2016
DOI: 10.1007/s10458-016-9340-x
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Positional scoring-based allocation of indivisible goods

Abstract: International audienceWe define a family of rules for dividing $m$ indivisible goods among agents, parameterized by a scoring vector and a social welfare aggregation function. We assume that agents' preferences over sets of goods are additive, but that the input is ordinal: each agent reports her preferences simply by ranking single goods. Similarly to positional scoring rules in voting, a scoring vector s = (s1, ... , sm) consists of m nonincreasing, nonnegative weights, where si is the score of a good assign… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
15
0

Year Published

2019
2019
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
5
3
1

Relationship

2
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 32 publications
(15 citation statements)
references
References 30 publications
0
15
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Some of the work does not assume any underlying cardinal preferences; instead, it aims to obtain guarantees defined directly in terms of the ordinal preferences. For example, Baumeister et al [2017] and use the socalled scoring vectors to convert agents' ordinal preferences into numerical proxies for their utility and then consider maximizing various notions of social welfare or guaranteeing various fairness properties in terms of such utilities.…”
Section: Fairnessmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Some of the work does not assume any underlying cardinal preferences; instead, it aims to obtain guarantees defined directly in terms of the ordinal preferences. For example, Baumeister et al [2017] and use the socalled scoring vectors to convert agents' ordinal preferences into numerical proxies for their utility and then consider maximizing various notions of social welfare or guaranteeing various fairness properties in terms of such utilities.…”
Section: Fairnessmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Despite its problem discussed in the previous section, the Borda-sum ranking is actually used in various occasions and, in particular, in the literature on fair division (see, e.g., Brams and Taylor 2000;Brams et al 2003;Brams and King 2005;Bouveret and Lang 2011;Baumeister et al 2017;Brams et al 2017 or Kilgour andVetschera 2018). However, many other potential applications do exist where a comparison of sets with fixed cardinality may be relevant.…”
Section: Borda-sum Ranking For Equal Cardinalitymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Recently, various papers explicitly use the sum of some kind of positional scores 1 with respect to the ranking of the single objects and, in particular, Borda scores 2 of its respective elements (and their sum of points) to compare the different sets (see, e.g., Brams and Taylor 2000;Brams et al 2003;Brams and King 2005;Bouveret and Lang 2011;Baumeister et al 2017;Brams et al 2017 or Kilgour and Vetschera 2018). In that literature the Borda-sum ranking is used to deal with issues such as efficiency, proportionality or envy-freeness, because these are hard to tackle with purely ordinal and non-additive information.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In voting, such a shift of scores would not matter (Hemaspaandra. For the allocation problem, however,Baumeister et al (2017) show that such a shift actually does matter.…”
mentioning
confidence: 95%