1998
DOI: 10.1016/s0047-2727(97)00049-2
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Progressive taxation and the social marginal cost of public funds

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
2

Citation Types

0
77
1
2

Year Published

2004
2004
2018
2018

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 77 publications
(80 citation statements)
references
References 11 publications
0
77
1
2
Order By: Relevance
“…The MCF, on the other hand, describes this same tax benefit system by considering one of many different possible marginal changes in the system. In this sense our exercise is fundamentally different from other papers, starting with Browning and Johnson (1984) and later expanded by, among others, Mayshar (1990) and Dahlby (1998), who explicitly quantify the trade-off at the margin. They do this by changing one specific element of the tax system, which can be identified as marginally changing the progressivity characteristics of the tax system (the demogrant in the case of Browning and Johnson (1984), one of the tax rates in a piece-wise linear system in the case of Dahlby (1998)) and then calculating the MCF.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 89%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The MCF, on the other hand, describes this same tax benefit system by considering one of many different possible marginal changes in the system. In this sense our exercise is fundamentally different from other papers, starting with Browning and Johnson (1984) and later expanded by, among others, Mayshar (1990) and Dahlby (1998), who explicitly quantify the trade-off at the margin. They do this by changing one specific element of the tax system, which can be identified as marginally changing the progressivity characteristics of the tax system (the demogrant in the case of Browning and Johnson (1984), one of the tax rates in a piece-wise linear system in the case of Dahlby (1998)) and then calculating the MCF.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 89%
“…Browning, 1976). Hansson and Stuart (1985) and Dahlby (1998), among others, extended the concept to marginal changes in progressive, piece-wise linear tax systems. Finally, Kleven & Kreiner (2006) also brought the extensive margin of labour supply on board when estimating the MCF.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…By using the latter approach to the marginal cost of funds, Sandmo (1998) and Slemrod and Yitzhaki (2001) include distributional aspects of distortionary linear taxation, while Gahvari (2006) extends it to nonlinear taxation. Using models with representative agents, Triest (1990), Håkonsen (1998), andDahlby (1998) develop yet another MCF concept relying on correcting the standard MCF measures with a ratio of the shadow value of public resources before and after the introduction of distortionary taxes. Up to this date, it remains unclear which MCF measure should be used in applied policy analysis.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Note that, given the linear speci…cation of (12), these values of course vary among observations. Table 5 5.2 The marginal cost of public funds…”
Section: Datamentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We note however that our estimates of the elasticities for the prime-age males are rather large, when compared to analogous studies in North America and Europe. 15 The linear speci…cation of (12) restricts the values of elasticities a priori. That is, to the extent that w=h (w) is larger, the compensated elasticities (income e¤ect) will be more positive (negative).…”
Section: Datamentioning
confidence: 99%