2002
DOI: 10.1006/jeth.2001.2914
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Quantal Response Equilibrium and Overbidding in Private-Value Auctions

Abstract: This paper reports the results of a private-values auction experiment in which expected costs of deviating from the Nash equilibrium bidding function are asymmetric, with the implication that upward deviations will be more likely in one treatment than in the other. Overbidding is observed in both treatments, but is more prevalent in the treatment where the costs of overbidding are lower. We specify and estimate a noisy (quantal response) model of equilibrium behavior. Estimated noise and risk aversion paramete… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

11
234
1

Year Published

2002
2002
2018
2018

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

3
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 366 publications
(246 citation statements)
references
References 19 publications
11
234
1
Order By: Relevance
“…The results of this paper suggest that the quantal response equilibrium may be useful in a wide class of applied econometric studies. With respect to the empirical study of auctions, initial attempts to develop methodologies for doing this in the contexts of both laboratory data (Goeree, Holt, and Palfrey, 2002) and field data (Bajari and Hortacsu, 2001) indicate that this approach is both feasible and promising. (12) CIT (12) CIT (12) CIT (12) CIT (12) CIT ( …”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The results of this paper suggest that the quantal response equilibrium may be useful in a wide class of applied econometric studies. With respect to the empirical study of auctions, initial attempts to develop methodologies for doing this in the contexts of both laboratory data (Goeree, Holt, and Palfrey, 2002) and field data (Bajari and Hortacsu, 2001) indicate that this approach is both feasible and promising. (12) CIT (12) CIT (12) CIT (12) CIT (12) CIT ( …”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In this model, sophisticated C f subjects have a strong incentive to forego current gains to ''teach'' their possibly adaptive partners to increase effort, but sophisticated C d subjects have no such incentive. 18 This…”
Section: Learning Strategic Teaching Mixed Strategies and Analogiementioning
confidence: 99%
“…FIRST-PRICE SEALED-BID AUCTIONS Goeree, Holt, and Palfrey [18] report experiments that revisit a controversial issue in the experimental auction literature: whether risk aversion can explain the common tendency of human subjects in first-price sealedbid auctions with private values to ''overbid'' relative to the risk-neutral Nash equilibrium. In response to Harrison's [19] ''flat-maximum'' critique of the original overbidding results, Friedman [14] noted that the costs of upward and downward deviations were approximately symmetric, so the weakness of subjects' incentives does not in itself explain overbidding: explaining systematic deviations from equilibrium requires asymmetric costs.…”
Section: Quantal Response Equilibrium Inmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…It is an equilibrium behavior for the follower to bid below his valuation with some probability, since the follower earns zero payoff in equilibrium and the leader will not be tempted to deviate as long as the follower puts a sufficient probability mass/density close to his valuation. 10 In Auction 2, if a group leader bids strictly above the follower's valuation (i.e., the latter is not binding), any bid below the follower's valuation can be an equilibrium response. Such a multiplicity should be taken account of in interpreting experimental data.…”
Section: Equilibrium Behavior In the First-price Auctionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…First, Bertrand behavior is not subject to bidders' risk attitudes, so the follower's behavior in FPBF and the dependence of a leader's bid on the follower's valuation -coefficients B 2 2 and B 3 2 -are robust to the risk aversion issue. Likewise, the qualitative response by a leader to the rival information, as described in FPBL2 and 10 In fact, given a random tie-breaking rule and a continuous strategy space, any equilibrium response by the follower must involve randomizing below his valuation (See Blume (2003)). Given a discrete strategy space (which is more relevant for our experiment), bidding one's valuation with probability one can be supported as an equilibrium (if the leader bids a unit above it with probability one), but bidding below his valuation can be also supported as an equilibrium.…”
Section: Equilibrium Behavior In the First-price Auctionmentioning
confidence: 99%