2013
DOI: 10.1016/j.jebo.2012.12.032
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Rational expectations and loss aversion: Potential output and welfare implications

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
5
0

Year Published

2016
2016
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7
2

Relationship

1
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 12 publications
(5 citation statements)
references
References 20 publications
0
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…to activate the mechanism previously discussed. This effect is also evident by direct inspection of equations (9), (10) and (12): a low implies a high value of the exponent in the terms of these equations and this, for example in the case of Y in (9), means that a change in brings about a stronger response of the equilibrium output.…”
Section: Discussion: the Economic Intuitionmentioning
confidence: 89%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…to activate the mechanism previously discussed. This effect is also evident by direct inspection of equations (9), (10) and (12): a low implies a high value of the exponent in the terms of these equations and this, for example in the case of Y in (9), means that a change in brings about a stronger response of the equilibrium output.…”
Section: Discussion: the Economic Intuitionmentioning
confidence: 89%
“…We first assume a log specification for consumption utility (i.e. ), which is commonly adopted in standard macroeconomic modelling (our results would not qualita- 10 A rigid labor market is characterised by a high , while an elastic one by a low .…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Most of the follow‐up literature, including this paper, employ a simplified version of the Prospect Theory by adopting only loss‐aversion and reference‐dependence (DellaVigna, ). Reference‐dependent preferences help explain ubiquitous phenomena such as excessive aversion to small risks in the laboratory (Kahneman and Tversky, ), endowment effect for inexperienced traders (Kahneman et al ., ), resistance of lowering consumption in response to bad news about future income (Bowman et al ., ), the reluctance to sell houses at a loss (Genesove and Mayer, ), equity premium puzzle in asset returns (Benartzi and Thaler, ; Barberis et al ., ), the disposition effect, that is, the tendency to sell winners rather than losers in financial markets (Odean, ), eliminating paradoxical effects of monetary variance in macroeconomic policy (Ciccarone and Marchetti, ), inefficient task allocation in contract theory (Daido et al ., ), the energy paradox (Greene, ), target earnings in labor supply decisions (Camerer et al ., ; Fehr and Goette, ), the tendency to insure against small risks (Sydnor, ), and effort in the employment relationship (Mas, ), among many others.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In economics and psychology, the concept of loss aversion has recently been used to account for the empirical finding that individuals place higher weight on losses than gains, violating the assumption of standard economic theory that tastes are unchanging (Kahneman, 2003). Theories of loss aversion have sprung up with proposed explanations for this ubiquitous phenomenon, occurring in financial markets (e.g., Benartzi & Thaler, 1995), consumption and savings patterns (e.g., Bowman, Minehart, & Rabin, 1999), macroeconomic policy (e.g., Ciccarone & Marchetti, 2013), contract theory (e.g., Daido et al, 2013), real estate transactions (e.g., Genesove & Mayer, 2001), the energy paradox (Greene, 2011), competitive behavior (e.g., Eisenkopf & Teyssier, 2013), and trade (Freund & Ozden, 2008;Tovar, 2009), among others.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%