2019
DOI: 10.1016/j.enpol.2019.110878
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Review of key international demand elasticities for major industrializing economies

Abstract: This report conducts a selective review of various estimates for energy demand responses. It emphasizes recent empirical studies that include trends from studies published after 2000. Emphasis is placed on the five major emerging or transitional economies in Brazil, China, India, Mexico and Russia, although other important nations like Chile and South Korea are also discussed when studies are available. The review focuses attention on the long-run responses to changes in prices and income after capital stock t… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

1
31
1
1

Year Published

2020
2020
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 52 publications
(34 citation statements)
references
References 71 publications
1
31
1
1
Order By: Relevance
“…The contribution of intermittent renewables to emission reductions falls to 49% (compared 35 Note that we define fuel switching as the change in the emission intensity of fossil-fuel-based generation technologies due to switching to fuels with a lower carbon content (either natural gas instead of coal or biomass instead of natural gas) or power plants with a higher conversion efficiency. 36 The mechanism is similar to the finding of Böhringer and Rosendahl [9] that an emission reduction target in combination with a quota for renewables promotes the dirtiest technology, meaning that coal stays and gas leaves the market. In our model, we do not have a green quota but, rather, a central planner investing in energy efficiency.…”
supporting
confidence: 60%
See 3 more Smart Citations
“…The contribution of intermittent renewables to emission reductions falls to 49% (compared 35 Note that we define fuel switching as the change in the emission intensity of fossil-fuel-based generation technologies due to switching to fuels with a lower carbon content (either natural gas instead of coal or biomass instead of natural gas) or power plants with a higher conversion efficiency. 36 The mechanism is similar to the finding of Böhringer and Rosendahl [9] that an emission reduction target in combination with a quota for renewables promotes the dirtiest technology, meaning that coal stays and gas leaves the market. In our model, we do not have a green quota but, rather, a central planner investing in energy efficiency.…”
supporting
confidence: 60%
“…As a default assumption, we set the ability to shed demand to the values shown in Table 1. Moreover, as indicated in Huntington et al [36] and Taylor et al [63], the ability to shift (called cross-price elasticity in those works) seems to be moderate in comparison to the ability to shed. Thus, we assume that the abilities to shift occurs in the four previous and subsequent cross-hours and is 10% of the ability to shed (see Table 1).…”
Section: Calibration Of the Numerical Modelmentioning
confidence: 95%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Two commonly cited figures come from Dahl [41], who estimates long-run price elasticities of oil demand for developing countries of − 0.13 to − 0.26, and Cooper [42], who estimates elasticities for developed countries from − 0.18 to − 0.45. A review of recent studies in Huntington et al [43] finds that the average demand elasticity across several studies in a variety of nations is − 0.15, with estimates of − 0.25 for the Middle East and − 0.26 for all non-OECD nations. Krupnick et al [44] estimate a median long-run price elasticity of demand for non-US consumption of − 0.5, with a 5th to 95th percentile range of − 0.42 to − 0.61.…”
Section: Estimating Non-us Emissionsmentioning
confidence: 99%