2018
DOI: 10.1016/j.econlet.2018.08.016
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Sectoral inflation and the Phillips curve: What has changed since the Great Recession?

Abstract: Using sectoral data at a medium level of aggregation, we find that price changes became less responsive to aggregate unemployment around 2009-2010. The slopes of the disaggregated Phillips curves diminished in many sectors, including housing and some services. We also document a decrease in sectoral inflation persistence, suggesting an increase in the weight of the forward-looking inflation expectation component and a decrease in the weight of the backward-looking component.

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
14
0

Year Published

2018
2018
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
4
2
1

Relationship

2
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 15 publications
(14 citation statements)
references
References 7 publications
0
14
0
Order By: Relevance
“…We find that it does. As noted above, using data only up through 2006 for coefficient estimation, we find that recursive forecasts from our specification (conditioned only on historical 7 See Luengo-Prado, Rao, and Sheremirov (2018). Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995) and Debelle and Laxton (1997) also draw attention to the weak relationship between positive slack and inflation.…”
Section: But Does This New Reduced-form Phillips Curve Specification mentioning
confidence: 55%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…We find that it does. As noted above, using data only up through 2006 for coefficient estimation, we find that recursive forecasts from our specification (conditioned only on historical 7 See Luengo-Prado, Rao, and Sheremirov (2018). Laxton, Meredith, and Rose (1995) and Debelle and Laxton (1997) also draw attention to the weak relationship between positive slack and inflation.…”
Section: But Does This New Reduced-form Phillips Curve Specification mentioning
confidence: 55%
“…A mismeasured gap will likely lead to the conclusion that forecasting performance is episodic (for example, Stock and Watson 2009) or that there is time variation in the inflation process, such as time variation in the coefficient on the activity variable (see evidence in Clark and McCracken 2006, Stock and Watson 2009, Vavra 2013and Luengo-Prado, Rao, and Sheremirov, 2018. This may explain the forecasting performance of the time-varying unobserved components model of Stock and Watson (2007).…”
Section: A4 Relation To Some Other Findings In the Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…A mismeasured gap will likely lead to the conclusion that forecasting performance is episodic (e.g., Stock and Watson 2009) or that there is time variation in the inflation process, such as time variation in the coefficient on the activity variable (see evidence in Clark and McCracken 2006, Stock and Watson 2009, Vavra 2014and Luengo-Prado, Rao and Sheremirov, 2017. This may explain the forecasting performance of the time-varying unobserved components model of Stock and Watson (2007).…”
Section: A4 Relation To Some Other Findings In the Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Using a richer model specification, this paper explains the true nature of the Phillips relationship, including its apparent weakening. In addition to rationalizing the missing disinflation puzzle, we provide a unified explanation of several other prominent recent findings, such as the odd behavior of the reverse-engineered NAIRU in Coibion and Gorodnichenko (2015), the fact that the Phillips relationship appears to be only episodically helpful in forecasting Watson, 2009, 2010), that it appears to have a convex-concave relationship (e.g., Barnes and Olivei 2003), that it is time-varying (e.g., McCracken 2006 or Stock andWatson 2007), and that it appears to have vanished after 2009 (Luengo-Prado, Rao, and Sheremirov, 2017). We do this without reference to the short-term unemployment rate (cf.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation