2012
DOI: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2011.05.022
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Spontaneous similarity discrimination in the evolution of cooperation

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
16
0

Year Published

2012
2012
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 26 publications
(16 citation statements)
references
References 31 publications
0
16
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Nevertheless, neither drifters that are strategic in behavior (behaving less altruistically in non-natal colonies) nor spiteful; (reducing fitness of non-natal colonies) prevent drifting from evolving through gains from indirect reciprocity. Previously cheating has been shown to be less likely when the cost of the beneficial act is small and reciprocators can be identified by an honest phenotypic marker or "tag" (Riolo et al, 2001;Colman et al, 2012). In the case of worker drifting, the cost is arguably trivial to nonexistent.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Nevertheless, neither drifters that are strategic in behavior (behaving less altruistically in non-natal colonies) nor spiteful; (reducing fitness of non-natal colonies) prevent drifting from evolving through gains from indirect reciprocity. Previously cheating has been shown to be less likely when the cost of the beneficial act is small and reciprocators can be identified by an honest phenotypic marker or "tag" (Riolo et al, 2001;Colman et al, 2012). In the case of worker drifting, the cost is arguably trivial to nonexistent.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Also, the tag in this case is simple and honest: a willingness to accept drifters. Reciprocating nests would be evident in the population by their relaxed acceptance threshold levels (Reeve, 1989;Masuda and Ohtsuki, 2007;Colman et al, 2012). There would be no need to evolve specific phenotypic markers, learn to recognize reciprocators, or to punish cheaters.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There is a small, but growing, number of models explicitly based on other games. Colman et al (2012) tested six games with speci c payo s that can be classi ed into versions of both dilemmas and co-ordination games. The analysis was however restricted to such small populations that inclusive tness is at work.…”
Section: Previous Modelsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The (far from straightforward) computational implementation of the argument amounts to a certificate of its soundness, but the relevance of the argument to cooperation in human and animal populations is limited by the requirement that the cooperating players have to be literally identical. However, if the cost of cooperation is c and the benefit to the other player(s) is b, with c < b as before, it is easy to prove that the payoff from cooperation exceeds that from defection whenever p > (b + c)/2b, where p is the probability that both players will choose the same strategy, and there is strong evidence from computational simulations with social dilemmas and a variety of other games that similarity discrimination evolves spontaneously and powerfully in the process of natural selection, with players cooperating selectively with co-players who are similar but not necessarily identical to themselves (Colman, Browning, & Pulford, 2012). It seems reasonable to conclude that similarity discrimination helps to explain cooperation and its evolution.…”
Section: Similaritymentioning
confidence: 99%