1973
DOI: 10.2307/2534084
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

State and Local Fiscal Behavior and Federal Grant Policy

Abstract: State and Local Fiscal Behavior and Federal Grant Policy PURCHASES BY STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS have long been the most rapidly rising component of aggregate demand. While real consumption and investment expenditures have both doubled since the end of the Korean war, and federal purchases have increased barely at all, state and local purchases of goods and services have almost tripled. They have grown at an annual average rate of 5.5 percent and now account for over 10 percent of real gross national product … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
2

Citation Types

2
95
0
7

Year Published

1996
1996
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 143 publications
(104 citation statements)
references
References 0 publications
2
95
0
7
Order By: Relevance
“…Thus, equalization transfers and other redistributive subsidies can influence the policies of recipient governments in the intended direction, i.e., resulting in the desired incentive effects, but may also induce adverse or undesirable incentive effects Smart, 2002 andRego, 2002). If the income elasticity of capital expenditure is greater than 1, when it receives the transfer the receiving government will take funds from current spending to allocate to investment (Bradford andOates, 1971 andGramlich et al, 1973). If the receiving governments are required to co-finance a percentage of the subsidised capital goods (compensatory transfers or matching grants), the donor and receiving administrations will share the investment cost, reducing the price of capital expenditure for the receiver.…”
Section: Problem Statement and Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…Thus, equalization transfers and other redistributive subsidies can influence the policies of recipient governments in the intended direction, i.e., resulting in the desired incentive effects, but may also induce adverse or undesirable incentive effects Smart, 2002 andRego, 2002). If the income elasticity of capital expenditure is greater than 1, when it receives the transfer the receiving government will take funds from current spending to allocate to investment (Bradford andOates, 1971 andGramlich et al, 1973). If the receiving governments are required to co-finance a percentage of the subsidised capital goods (compensatory transfers or matching grants), the donor and receiving administrations will share the investment cost, reducing the price of capital expenditure for the receiver.…”
Section: Problem Statement and Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…As Gramlich et al (1973) and Oates (1999) point out, standard theory leaves little room to explain the existence of both categorical block grants (i.e., flat-rate subsidies that have to be used for certain specific purposes), and closed-ended matching grants (i.e. transfers that subsidize the costs of specific goods with a fixed maximum amount).…”
Section: Problem Statement and Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…A second group holds that omitted variables could also falsely support the flypaper effect if unobserved community"s characteristics, which affect the technology or effective cost of public spending, were systematically related with citizens" income (Hamilton, 1983). The flypaper puzzle, however, remains after using truly unconditional grants (Inman, 1971;Gramlich and Galper, 1973;Bowman, 1974) or controlling for population characteristics. A third group holds that the standard model of a citizen"s fiscal choice might be misspecified because either the citizen confuses the income effect generated by unconditional transfers with a price effect that reduces the average effective cost of public spending (Courant et al, 1979;Oates, 1979), he/she is not fully informed and fails to see the public budget (Filimon et al, 1982) or, even when fully informed, he/she might not behave completely rationally (Hinesand Thaler, 1995).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There appears to be strong empirical evidence in support of greater impact on local public spending from an increase in grants than from an equivalent increase in residential income. This regularity was called the "flypaper effect" by Gramlich and Galper (1973). Although the median voter models can be modified to account for flypaper effects, it appears rather artificial to allow for different tax and spending responses of grants-in-aid and residential income when the median voter is considered to be the decision-maker.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%