1994
DOI: 10.3386/w4764
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Taxes and Fringe Benefits Offered by Employers

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
18
0

Year Published

1999
1999
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 28 publications
(18 citation statements)
references
References 2 publications
0
18
0
Order By: Relevance
“…4 A handful of previous work has explored some aspect of the provision of other insurance benefits but has produced little evidence about takeup decisions. For example Gentry and Peress (1994), find a significant effect of tax rates on employer decisions to offer vision and dental insurance and the estimates of Woodbury (1983) imply that health and life insurance benefits are highly substitutable with wages. These studies had only aggregate data available, however, and they had to rely on variation in tax rates, either by income-level (Woodbury, 1983) or by state (Gentry and Peress, 1994) to identify benefit price effects.…”
Section: Previous Literaturementioning
confidence: 95%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…4 A handful of previous work has explored some aspect of the provision of other insurance benefits but has produced little evidence about takeup decisions. For example Gentry and Peress (1994), find a significant effect of tax rates on employer decisions to offer vision and dental insurance and the estimates of Woodbury (1983) imply that health and life insurance benefits are highly substitutable with wages. These studies had only aggregate data available, however, and they had to rely on variation in tax rates, either by income-level (Woodbury, 1983) or by state (Gentry and Peress, 1994) to identify benefit price effects.…”
Section: Previous Literaturementioning
confidence: 95%
“…For example Gentry and Peress (1994), find a significant effect of tax rates on employer decisions to offer vision and dental insurance and the estimates of Woodbury (1983) imply that health and life insurance benefits are highly substitutable with wages. These studies had only aggregate data available, however, and they had to rely on variation in tax rates, either by income-level (Woodbury, 1983) or by state (Gentry and Peress, 1994) to identify benefit price effects. The price variation available in the data employed here is more clearly exogenous and allows us to estimate the effect of premium on the takeup of a variety of fringe benefits.…”
Section: Previous Literaturementioning
confidence: 95%
“…Previous studies have shown corporate status (Jensen and Gabel, 1992;Morrissey et al, 1994) and the value of the tax exemption (Leibowitz and Chernew, 1992;Gentry and Peress, 1994) increase the probability that a ® rm will provide health insurance and other fringe bene-® ts. There is little reason to expect that ® rm's corporate status will directly a ect the mix of part-time and full-time employees it hires.…”
Section: Econometric Speci Ficati Onmentioning
confidence: 98%
“…The company will provide the extra insurance benefit and reduce monthly salaries by somewhere between $25 and $29.85, leaving both the firm and its workers better off even though the additional coverage is socially wasteful. Clearly, the private incentive to provide additional fringe benefits (and the size of the resulting social-welfare loss) increases with the marginal tax rate, as Long and Scott (1982), Woodbury (1983), and Gentry and Peress (1994) show. Given such tax distortions, the public-policy concern should be that firms are spending too much on nonwage benefits, rather than too little.…”
Section: Why Employers Provide Non-wage Benefitsmentioning
confidence: 92%