2017
DOI: 10.1016/j.joep.2017.07.002
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Team incentives and leadership

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
5
0
1

Year Published

2019
2019
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 21 publications
(6 citation statements)
references
References 52 publications
0
5
0
1
Order By: Relevance
“…Or alternatively speaking, finding even small significant effort deviations caused by SOCs in such a highly transparent job profile seems to be an indication to conclude that the effect should be significant and more relevant in less transparent jobs resulting in a significant reduction of team productivity. As a practical implication, employers outside the sports industry should intensify the monitoring of their employees' effort decisions after an SOC announcement (e.g., giving more attention to effort statistics or improve monitoring practices) so that they have better opportunities to avoid shirking behavior by offering monetary or nonmonetary incentives (Drouvelis, Nosenzo, & Sefton, ; Goldsmith et al, ). However, strong increases of the employees' monitoring might be negatively (e.g., missing trust) perceived by them, which in return could lead to a crowding out effect of their motivation (Frey & Jegen, ; James, ).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Or alternatively speaking, finding even small significant effort deviations caused by SOCs in such a highly transparent job profile seems to be an indication to conclude that the effect should be significant and more relevant in less transparent jobs resulting in a significant reduction of team productivity. As a practical implication, employers outside the sports industry should intensify the monitoring of their employees' effort decisions after an SOC announcement (e.g., giving more attention to effort statistics or improve monitoring practices) so that they have better opportunities to avoid shirking behavior by offering monetary or nonmonetary incentives (Drouvelis, Nosenzo, & Sefton, ; Goldsmith et al, ). However, strong increases of the employees' monitoring might be negatively (e.g., missing trust) perceived by them, which in return could lead to a crowding out effect of their motivation (Frey & Jegen, ; James, ).…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Egocentrism poses a hazard to stakeholders because it may cause owner-managers to favor self-regarding over other-regarding interests (Thompson & Loewenstein, 1992). The problem of egocentrism for economic value creation is that the owner-manager's pursuit of selfregarding interests can make it difficult for the owner-manager to reach win-win agreements with stakeholders (Drouvelis, Nosenzo, & Sefton, 2017). Barney (2018: 3319) points to this hazard when arguing the following:…”
Section: Appropriation Rights and Egocentrism Hazardsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Drouvelis et al . (2017) examine a similar team‐production setting where the nonleader members vote on how much of team output to make available to the leader for allocation. They find that overall team production increases in the team leader treatment compared to the revenue‐sharing treatment.…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…The primary research question addressed in our study centers on the flexibility in allocation rules available to the third party tasked with allocating the collective good to group members. Prior experimental research has shown that third party allocators can lead to increased provision of the collective good (Stoddard et al ., 2014; Drouvelis et al ., 2017). However, as discussed in the next section, these studies vary in several dimensions from ours.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%