“…According to the RH, if one item is recognized (e.g., Prague) and the other is not (e.g., Erdenet), then the recognized item is inferred to have the higher value on the criterion dimension (on which the objects’ true values are unknown). The RH has been extensively investigated (e.g., Goldstein & Gigerenzer, 2002 ; Hilbig, Michalkiewicz, Castela, Pohl, & Erdfelder, 2015 ; Kämmer, Gaissmaier, Reimer, & Schermuly, 2014 ; McCloy, Beaman, Frosch, & Goddard, 2010 ; Newell & Shanks, 2004 ; Pachur, Bröder, & Marewski, 2008 ) and is a prime example of a frugal heuristic that exploits one good reason (recognition) that leads to surprisingly accurate judgments in many real-world domains because familiar and novel items often differ systematically on relevant dimensions such as quantity or success (e.g., sports teams, brands, stocks, and colleges that are recognized tend to be more successful). Even though people may not always give recognition primacy over other information in strict non-compensatory fashion, as originally specified for the RH (Glöckner, Hilbig, Jekel, 2014 ; Hilbig et al 2015 ; Newell & Shanks, 2004 ), research on how recognition is systematically exploited as a cue remains important (for overviews, see Marewski, Pohl, & Vitouch, 2010 ; Pachur, Todd, Gigerenzer, Schooler, & Goldstein, 2011 ).…”