2003
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.405062
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Dixit-Pindyck and the Arrow-Fisher-Hanemann-Henry Option Values are not Equivalent

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
5
0

Year Published

2004
2004
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
5
1

Relationship

1
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 7 publications
(5 citation statements)
references
References 0 publications
0
5
0
Order By: Relevance
“…8 This value can be decomposed into the value of immediately trying and giving birth and the value of having the option to try and give birth later. Note that there is no information accruing in time, meaning that this option value, which we call "option value of giving birth" corresponds to the "pure postponement value" defined by Mensink and Requate (2005), as opposed to the option value for receiving information or "quasi-option value", which is the concept developed by Arrow, Fisher, Hanemann, and Henry (see Arrow and Fisher (1974), Henry (1974), and Fisher and Hanemann (1987)). This pure postponement value is however part of the Dixit-Pindyck option (see Dixit (1992), Pindyck (1991), and Dixit and Pindyck (1994)) which is the sum of the pure postponement value and of the quasi-option value.…”
Section: Age At Birthmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…8 This value can be decomposed into the value of immediately trying and giving birth and the value of having the option to try and give birth later. Note that there is no information accruing in time, meaning that this option value, which we call "option value of giving birth" corresponds to the "pure postponement value" defined by Mensink and Requate (2005), as opposed to the option value for receiving information or "quasi-option value", which is the concept developed by Arrow, Fisher, Hanemann, and Henry (see Arrow and Fisher (1974), Henry (1974), and Fisher and Hanemann (1987)). This pure postponement value is however part of the Dixit-Pindyck option (see Dixit (1992), Pindyck (1991), and Dixit and Pindyck (1994)) which is the sum of the pure postponement value and of the quasi-option value.…”
Section: Age At Birthmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…According to a 2011 Energy Commerce Committee report, BTEX compounds --benzene, toluene, ethylbenzene, and xylene, all known carcinogens -appeared in at least 60 fracking products in use between 2005 and 2009. in a dynamic programming application, and Dixit and Pindyck (1994) bring the real options approach to the mainstream environmental and resource economics literature. Mensink and Requate (2005) point out that the Dixit and Pindyck option value (DPOV) and the QOV are not necessarily equivalent. Specifically, they find that when postponement is initially beneficial and the net present value of a project is strictly positive, the DPOV captures the QOV in addition to the value created from doing the project in a later period in the absence of learning.…”
Section: Fracking Damagesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Traeger (2014) extends Mensink and Requate (2005) and provides a general relationship between QOV and DPOV: the QOV is the value of learning conditional on postponement and the DPOV is the net value of postponement under learning. The literature proves two important properties of the QOV that are relevant to our model.…”
Section: Learning About Environmental Risksmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Grappling with the theoretical distinction was muddied further by the fact that financial economics has yet another concept of option value, developed for application to natural resource economics by Dixit and Pindyck (1994). Fortunately, a number of authors, particularly Hanemann (1989), Mensink and Requate (2005), and Traeger (2014), have provided unifying syntheses of and clarity among these three distinct concepts. Furthermore, terminology appears to have evolved to distinguish between the 'Arrow-Fisher-Henry' quasi-option value and the 'Dixit-Pindyck' option value.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%