2016
DOI: 10.1086/685447
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Electoral Benefits of Opportunistic Election Timing

Abstract: In this paper, we present a comparative analysis of the effect of opportunistic elections on the incumbent's electoral performance. The existing literature on parliamentary dissolution and election timing generates contradictory expectations about the ability of incumbent governments to benefit from strategically timed elections. We evaluate these competing hypotheses, drawing on an original dataset of 321 parliamentary elections in 27 East and West European countries, observed from 1945 or democratization to … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

2
70
0

Year Published

2018
2018
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
5
2

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 52 publications
(72 citation statements)
references
References 44 publications
2
70
0
Order By: Relevance
“…In reality, elections are not fixed in the overwhelming majority of parliamentary democracies and only a very small minority of elections could be described as strategically timed or “opportunistic” (Schleiter and Tavits 2016). Indeed, an accounting of over 608 European governments by Seki and Williams (2014) reveals that at least 62% of cabinets terminate in conditions that are not constitutionally mandated elections and are extraordinarily unlikely to be the product of strategic electoral timing—the resignation of the prime minister (for health reasons or otherwise), internal dissent, or loss of parliamentary support.…”
Section: Public Spendingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In reality, elections are not fixed in the overwhelming majority of parliamentary democracies and only a very small minority of elections could be described as strategically timed or “opportunistic” (Schleiter and Tavits 2016). Indeed, an accounting of over 608 European governments by Seki and Williams (2014) reveals that at least 62% of cabinets terminate in conditions that are not constitutionally mandated elections and are extraordinarily unlikely to be the product of strategic electoral timing—the resignation of the prime minister (for health reasons or otherwise), internal dissent, or loss of parliamentary support.…”
Section: Public Spendingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…2007;Adams and Somer-Topcu 2009;Somer-Topcu 2009;Ezrow 2010;Adams et al 2011;Schleiter and Tavits 2014).The analysis requires a measure of issue scope in election campaigns. Like recent work on the effect of the economy and intra-party politics on election campaigns and studies of policy agendas(Johnand Jennings 2010; Jennings et al 2011; Stoll 2011; Boydstun et al 2014; Greene and O'Brien 2016; Greene 2016a; Van Heck 2016), I measure the concentration and number of issues in parties' platforms using a function of issue diversity, an increasingly important topic in numerous areas of political research.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The evidence suggests that being able to choose times of real or perceived government popularity and favorable economic cycles are not the only advantages incumbent government parties gain from the ability to call early elections. Whether this funding advantage might contribute to the apparent incumbent vote gains from early elections (Schleiter and Tavits, 2016) is a more open question.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…27 The mechanism for an incumbency advantage in private contributions might also change if the motivation of the donor is to buy access to policymakers. If early elections signal a higher chance of winning for the incumbent, see Schleiter and Tavits (2016), this might make access-oriented donors more likely to donate to the incumbent. I owe this alternative mechanisms to a previous commenter.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation