1995
DOI: 10.2307/2137752
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Evolutionary Demography of the Fertility-Mortality Quasi-Equilibrium

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
11
0

Year Published

2000
2000
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
7
2

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 27 publications
(12 citation statements)
references
References 48 publications
0
11
0
Order By: Relevance
“…(4) See also Davis (1963). On some of the social, economic and psychological mechanisms which might help to re-establish some rough measure of equilibrium, see, for example, Carey and Lopreato (1995) and Cleland (2001). (5) It is generally believed that the only other phenomenon in human experience that might possibly be termed a`demographic transition' (that which occurred around the time of the Neolithic revolution) probably involved a rise in the birth rate as a lagged response to a rise in the death rate (see Coale, 1975).…”
Section: Notesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…(4) See also Davis (1963). On some of the social, economic and psychological mechanisms which might help to re-establish some rough measure of equilibrium, see, for example, Carey and Lopreato (1995) and Cleland (2001). (5) It is generally believed that the only other phenomenon in human experience that might possibly be termed a`demographic transition' (that which occurred around the time of the Neolithic revolution) probably involved a rise in the birth rate as a lagged response to a rise in the death rate (see Coale, 1975).…”
Section: Notesmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We identify it as such because the theory assumes that fertility is all about maximizing inclusive fitness rather than economic benefits. The authors of this theory, Carey and Lopreato (1995), argue that the main determinant of the level of fertility is the level of mortality. According to them, humans have evolved a "two-survivingchildren psychology" in which they gear their total fertility to the frequency with which offspring survive to adulthood.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Preferences for two-child families (Carey and Lopreato 1995; Morita et al 2015; Sobotka and Beaujouan 2014) and a disinclination to produce an only child are well established (Blake 1974) and fit well with these findings. In addition, these patterns show that more people reproduce and have at least one child than would be expected on the basis of a Poisson process with such a low mean.…”
Section: Descriptive Analysis Of Reproductive Patternsmentioning
confidence: 59%
“…It seems possible that the transition to parities above two is much less dependent on resources and that other influences, such as decisions made by those in an individual’s social network or other idiosyncratic factors gain prominence (e.g., Angrist and Evans 1998; Balbo and Barban 2014). In other words, economic factors may influence the desired goal of two children (Carey and Lopreato 1995; Morita et al 2012; Sobotka and Beaujouan 2014), whereas the desire for higher parities may be more strongly influenced by noneconomic factors. As an example, families are more likely to have a third child when the first two children are of the same sex (Angrist and Evans 1998).…”
Section: Longitudinal Analysis Of the Association Between Wealth And mentioning
confidence: 99%