2017
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.3093871
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Finance Uncertainty Multiplier

Abstract: We show theoretically and empirically how real and …nancial frictions amplify the impact of uncertainty shocks on …rms'investment, employment, debt (term structure of debt growth), and cash holding. We start by building a model with real and …nancial frictions, alongside uncertainty shocks, and show how adding …nancial frictions to the model roughly doubles the negative impact of uncertainty shocks on investment and hiring. The reason is higher uncertainty induces the standard negative real-options e¤ects on t… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

5
54
0

Year Published

2017
2017
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 46 publications
(59 citation statements)
references
References 109 publications
5
54
0
Order By: Relevance
“…This second finding is consistent with the theoretical literature on "endogenous uncertainty," which contends that uncertainty is rather a consequence, not a cause, of declining economic activity, as, for example, in Van Nieuwerburgh and Veldkamp (2006), Bachmann and Moscarini (2012), Fajgelbaum, Taschereau-Dumouchel, and Schaal (2017), Gourio (2014), Navarro (2014), and Plante, Richter, and Throckmorton (2018). The fact that the relationship between uncertainty and real activity may not be constant over time is consistent with theoretical models that show how the effects of heightened uncertainty can be amplified in extreme conditions such as high financial stress (e.g., Alfaro, Bloom, & Lin, 2018;Arellano, Bai, & Kehoe, 2018;Gilchrist, Sim, & Zakrajsek, 2014) or when monetary policy is constrained by the zero lower bound (Basu & Bundick, 2017).…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 67%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…This second finding is consistent with the theoretical literature on "endogenous uncertainty," which contends that uncertainty is rather a consequence, not a cause, of declining economic activity, as, for example, in Van Nieuwerburgh and Veldkamp (2006), Bachmann and Moscarini (2012), Fajgelbaum, Taschereau-Dumouchel, and Schaal (2017), Gourio (2014), Navarro (2014), and Plante, Richter, and Throckmorton (2018). The fact that the relationship between uncertainty and real activity may not be constant over time is consistent with theoretical models that show how the effects of heightened uncertainty can be amplified in extreme conditions such as high financial stress (e.g., Alfaro, Bloom, & Lin, 2018;Arellano, Bai, & Kehoe, 2018;Gilchrist, Sim, & Zakrajsek, 2014) or when monetary policy is constrained by the zero lower bound (Basu & Bundick, 2017).…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 67%
“…Finally, the estimated IRFs also line up with several contributions in the literature that highlight how uncertainty shocks have had larger effects after the GFC. This can be due to large financial frictions, as in Alfaro et al (2018), Caggiano, Castelnuovo, Delrio, and Robinson (2017), and Gilchrist et al (2014), or to the presence of the zero lower bound, as in Caggiano, Castelnuovo, and Pellegrino (2017) and Basu and Bundick (2017). They also support theoretical and empirical research that highlights how uncertainty shocks might have time-varying effects that depend on different macroeconomic conditions, such as the level of financial frictions (Alessandri and Mumtaz, 2018;Alfaro et al, 2018;Gilchrist et al, 2014), the stance of the business cycle (Cacciatore & Ravenna, 2016;Caggiano et al, 2014), or the stance of monetary policy (Basu & Bundick, 2017;Caggiano, Castelnuovo, & Pellegrino, 2017).…”
Section: Figurementioning
confidence: 99%
“…Source: Bloomberg, Consensus Economics, Dow Jones Factiva, GfK (research on behalf of the European Commission), Thomson Reuters Datastream, www.policyuncertainty.com and authors' calculations. 11 Guiso and Parigi, 1999;Alfaro, Bloom and Lin, 2018;Smietanka, Bloom and Mizen, 2018. very little increase in stock market volatility (also shown on Figure 2). Other indicators that combine a range of macro data were in between the two but do not imply that Brexit was a historically large uncertainty shock ( Figure 2 also shows a principal-component-based measure used by the Bank of England and described by Haddow et al (2013) and a measure of macro uncertainty that estimates the conditional variance of the unforecastable component common to a large number of macroeconomic variables, of the type suggested by Jurado, Ludvigson and Ng (2015) and estimated for the UK by Redl (2017)).…”
Section: Developments In Uncertainty Indicators Since Brexitmentioning
confidence: 78%
“…Thomas (2013), Gopinath et al (2015), Chaney et al (2015) and Alfaro, Bloom and Lin (2016), when the collateral constraint parameter is set to 0. The pattern of firms unable to obtain external funds, and forced to save their way to an optimal size, is the same; they are also present in microfounded models of debt issuance, such as Cooley and Quadrini (2001), Hennessy and Whited (2007), and Gilchrist, Sim and Zakrajšek (2014).…”
Section: Model Descriptionmentioning
confidence: 99%