Recent scholarship makes the case that from the seventeenth through the nineteenth centuries, French peasants were just as effective as the large farmers of England in raising agricultural productivity when they had access to urban markets. This article shows that the peasants of the old regime province of Languedoc had access to urban demand and market opportunities, and brought about economic growth, but only by dint of massive increases of labour inputs. The results were paltry increases in labour productivity and the standard of living. The case of Languedoc demonstrates that the study of the social context helps scholars evaluate a society's potential for economic development far more than does the study of its markets.
2Stephen J. Miller from Paris. The market opportunity for trade with the towns is nowadays advanced as the basic explanation for gains in economic productivity. 2 Philip Hoffman, in particular, ascribes all of the distinctive traits of rural France to the influence of markets. Sharecropping, Hoffman argues, permitted landowners to gain value from poor peasants lacking the financial reserves to assume the costs of a fixed-term lease. It lent itself to more effective monitoring of the husbandry than did landlord/tenant relationships and became the logical form of rental agreement for proprietors residing near their holdings. When markets called for crops such as vines, which required meticulous husbandry, sharecropping helped the landowners to supervise the work closely. Farm sizes also responded to market stimuli, Hoffman maintains, as many proprietors had opportunities for profit in viticulture and established small plots to better focus on the careful husbandry it required. English proprietors had opportunities in livestock, which called for large farms and little labour. They extended their landholdings to reduce costs and obtain the full benefits of trade. 3 Hoffman developed original data to demonstrate the propensity of French farmers to increase productivity when they had access to markets. Prices for land, labour, leases, capital, and commodities permit a calculation of production minus the cost of its factors, or 'total factor productivity'. The data show that productivity rose 7.7 per cent between 1650 to 74 and 1750 to 1774, and another 6.5 per cent (.3 per cent a year) between 1750 to 1774 and 1775 to 1789 in the Paris basin. These rates are 'comparable or superior to those achieved across the English Channel'. 4 Overall, productivity rose in Bretteville in Normandy in the sixteenth century, the southeast and Paris basin in the seventeenth century, and the Albigeois, Beaujolais, and Paris basin after 1750. 'Such growth matched the performance of farmers in England, and it could approach the best that could be achieved in early modern Europe'. 5 Labour productivity in agriculture rose twenty-seven per cent for France as a whole between 1500 and 1800. 6 Hoffman argues that French farmers did not achieve these gains through a transformation of the social structure or technology, rad...