2020
DOI: 10.1111/caje.12445
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The macroeconomic impact of NAFTA termination

Abstract: US President Trump has threatened to leave the North American Free Trade Agreement. How much would each member country gain or lose if this threat were carried out? Would trade imbalances within the region diminish? What would the transition to new production and consumption patterns look like? I provide quantitative answers to these questions using a dynamic general equilibrium model with a multi‐sector input–output production structure, heterogeneous firms that make forward‐looking export participation decis… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
12
0

Year Published

2021
2021
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 19 publications
(12 citation statements)
references
References 60 publications
0
12
0
Order By: Relevance
“…and Wang (2011); search frictions as in Drozd and Nosal (2012); di¤erence between the adjustments in extensive and intensive margins of trade as in Arkolakis, Eaton, and Kortum (2012); …xed versus variable trade costs or investments in reducing future export costs as in Alessandria, Choi, and Ruhl (2014); the speed of adjustment of capital in the distribution sector as in Crucini and Davis (2016); adjustment of capacity in bilateral network links as in Anderson and Yotov (2017); plant-level irreversibility in the structure of inputs used in production as in Ramanarayanan 2017; …xed and sunk costs of export participation as in Fitzgerald and Haller (2018); or adjustment frictions in factor markets as in Steinberg (2018).…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…and Wang (2011); search frictions as in Drozd and Nosal (2012); di¤erence between the adjustments in extensive and intensive margins of trade as in Arkolakis, Eaton, and Kortum (2012); …xed versus variable trade costs or investments in reducing future export costs as in Alessandria, Choi, and Ruhl (2014); the speed of adjustment of capital in the distribution sector as in Crucini and Davis (2016); adjustment of capacity in bilateral network links as in Anderson and Yotov (2017); plant-level irreversibility in the structure of inputs used in production as in Ramanarayanan 2017; …xed and sunk costs of export participation as in Fitzgerald and Haller (2018); or adjustment frictions in factor markets as in Steinberg (2018).…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The work closest to this article is by Steinberg (2022Steinberg ( , 2020. Steinberg (2022) develops a partial equilibrium model of exporting where new exporters to a destination grow over time by attracting new customers, similar to Arkolakis (2010).…”
Section: MIXmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…On a related matter but in a different context—with a closed economy—Atalay (2017) estimated a similar production function with intermediate goods instead of energy, and also found elasticities of substitution close to zero, between 0.02 and 0.05. Using these results in his calibration strategy, Steinberg (2019, 2020) used a Leontieff production function very similar to ours with capital/labor inputs and intermediate inputs.…”
Section: Data and Calibrationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This paper is also linked to the literature of applied general equilibrium models of trade, surveyed by Kehoe et al (2017), that is widely used to evaluate the effects of trade reforms. Recent examples are Steinberg (2019), that studies the impact of trade disruptions emerging from Brexit, and Steinberg (2020), which focuses on the consequences of the end of NAFTA. In these models specialization is due to sectorial productivity differences, while in ours it is caused by factor endowment differences.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%