2005
DOI: 10.1016/j.jdeveco.2004.08.007
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The perversity of preferences: GSP and developing country trade policies, 1976–2000

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

0
75
0

Year Published

2006
2006
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
6
2

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 102 publications
(78 citation statements)
references
References 23 publications
0
75
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Few researchers have attempted to estimate the overall effect of the GSP+ One recent study by Ozden and Reinhardt finds that the U+S+ GSP is not associated with an increase in trade+ 27 We expand their analysis by surveying all preference schemes in a variety of political contexts+ This allows us to quantify the effect of GSP-type preferences around the world, and to study the interaction between the GATT0WTO and the GSP+ To summarize, the concepts of standing and embeddedness can help one understand when and for whom international institutions matter+ In the domain of trade, the GATT0WTO should promote exchange not merely among formal members, 26+ Viner 1950 introduced criteria for evaluating PTAs: agreements can be said to increase welfare if they lead to more trade creation than trade diversion+ His criterion was subsequently used in empirical studies; see, for example, Corden 1976;Bhagwati and Panagariya 1996;Frankel 1997;and Lawrence 1999, most of which found that PTAs increase trade when they lead to significant reductions in trade barriers and when the signatories trade extensively with each other+ For recent work on the political origins of PTAs, see Mansfield and Reinhardt 2003;andMilner 1999+ 27+ Ozden andReinhardt 2005+ but more broadly among all countries and territories with legal standing+ Moreover, the GATT0WTO should be evaluated along with other trade agreements+ The remainder of the article addresses these propositions+…”
Section: Unidirectional Trade Agreements: the Generalized System Of Pmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Few researchers have attempted to estimate the overall effect of the GSP+ One recent study by Ozden and Reinhardt finds that the U+S+ GSP is not associated with an increase in trade+ 27 We expand their analysis by surveying all preference schemes in a variety of political contexts+ This allows us to quantify the effect of GSP-type preferences around the world, and to study the interaction between the GATT0WTO and the GSP+ To summarize, the concepts of standing and embeddedness can help one understand when and for whom international institutions matter+ In the domain of trade, the GATT0WTO should promote exchange not merely among formal members, 26+ Viner 1950 introduced criteria for evaluating PTAs: agreements can be said to increase welfare if they lead to more trade creation than trade diversion+ His criterion was subsequently used in empirical studies; see, for example, Corden 1976;Bhagwati and Panagariya 1996;Frankel 1997;and Lawrence 1999, most of which found that PTAs increase trade when they lead to significant reductions in trade barriers and when the signatories trade extensively with each other+ For recent work on the political origins of PTAs, see Mansfield and Reinhardt 2003;andMilner 1999+ 27+ Ozden andReinhardt 2005+ but more broadly among all countries and territories with legal standing+ Moreover, the GATT0WTO should be evaluated along with other trade agreements+ The remainder of the article addresses these propositions+…”
Section: Unidirectional Trade Agreements: the Generalized System Of Pmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Hence, the political balance shifts in favour of the import-competing sectors, which could result in slower progress toward the dismantling of trade barriers. Özden and Reinhardt (2005) offer empirical evidence in favour of this hypothesis. Looking at beneficiaries of the US GSP from 1976 to 2000 -and considering the potential endogeneity problems -they find that countries that are dropped from the GSP scheme adopt more liberal trade policies than countries that remain eligible.…”
Section: 3mentioning
confidence: 94%
“…Another potential negative effect of trade preferences, pointed out by Özden and Reinhardt (2005), is that they may slow down the developing countries' own trade liberalization. While import-competing sectors may have an incentive to lobby for trade barriers, this political pressure is often thought to be counteracted by the export sectors who can be expected to lobby for trade liberalization at home in order to achieve better market access in their export markets.…”
Section: 3mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Özden and Reinhardt (2003) argue that GSP schemes reduce the need for the export sector in beneficiary countries to oppose protectionist policies by their own government. Vested interests in both the export and import-competing sectors are created that resist change to the status quo, in particular further multilateral trade liberalization.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Vested interests in both the export and import-competing sectors are created that resist change to the status quo, in particular further multilateral trade liberalization. Conversely, Özden and Reinhardt (2003) establish empirically that sometimes when GSP eligibility is withdrawn and access to export markets becomes conditional on a country's own trade policy on the basis of reciprocity, countries reduce their protectionist policies and reap associated gains in efficiency and competitiveness.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%