2003
DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.212
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The potential consequences of alternative exchange rate regimes: A study of three candidate regions

Abstract: This paper examines the macroeconomic consequences of selecting alternative exchange rate regimes of countries in three regions. In particular, it studies whether Austria, the Netherlands, Canada and New Zealand made the right monetary regime choices between 1970 and 2000. We focus on the role of asymmetric shocks as a core determinant for the evaluation of various monetary regimes by studying the impact of a hard peg, a full monetary union, or floating exchange rates (with or without inflation targeting) on s… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
7
0

Year Published

2004
2004
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
5
1

Relationship

1
5

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 9 publications
(8 citation statements)
references
References 36 publications
1
7
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Impulse responses, consistent with the DSGE model, show that responses to foreign interest rate shocks that are orthogonalized, and thus not correlated with EMBS (balance sheet strength), are smaller than responses to foreign interest rate shocks that are not orthogonalized. Furthermore, the results show that the exclusion or inclusion of EMBS can produce apparently conflicting results: under flexible exchange rate regimes, output response is smaller in the model with EMBS, in keeping with the findings of the literature; however, under relatively fixed regimes when EMBS are excluded, output response is smaller (see Hochreiter et al 2003;Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger 2003;Bergvall 2005;Hoffmann 2007). These results, together with the fact that fixed exchange rate regimes are vulnerable to speculative attacks, suggest that exchange rate intervention (a managed float) without a formal commitment to a peg may do a better job of insulating economies from external shocks than a clean float.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 76%
“…Impulse responses, consistent with the DSGE model, show that responses to foreign interest rate shocks that are orthogonalized, and thus not correlated with EMBS (balance sheet strength), are smaller than responses to foreign interest rate shocks that are not orthogonalized. Furthermore, the results show that the exclusion or inclusion of EMBS can produce apparently conflicting results: under flexible exchange rate regimes, output response is smaller in the model with EMBS, in keeping with the findings of the literature; however, under relatively fixed regimes when EMBS are excluded, output response is smaller (see Hochreiter et al 2003;Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger 2003;Bergvall 2005;Hoffmann 2007). These results, together with the fact that fixed exchange rate regimes are vulnerable to speculative attacks, suggest that exchange rate intervention (a managed float) without a formal commitment to a peg may do a better job of insulating economies from external shocks than a clean float.…”
Section: Introductionsupporting
confidence: 76%
“…For example, the model here, a version which was used in Hochreiter, Korinek, and Siklos (2003), is richer than most in that it admits a role for fiscal policy. However, in other respects, it is more in the spirit of the Mundell-Fleming type of macro model than the new open economy macro models (NOEM) that have recently gained popularity.…”
Section: Counterfactualsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…18 The parameters are estimated via GMM, using a 16 Also, see Hochreiter et al (2003) who explore the sensitivity of counterfactual experiments in this context to assumptions about the stationarity of some of the series considered here. 17 An attraction of using instrument rules is that they are less sensitive to the assumed structure of the economy as would be true of optimal rules (e.g., Levin & Williams, 2003).…”
Section: Estimation Of Policy Rulesmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…On the other hand, the Maastricht model of monetary dominance and convergence includes several thresholds on key macroeconomic fundamentals for the sake of the establishment of a currency area. For instance, for a country to be considered a potential candidate for a monetary union, it is required to have a fiscal budget deficit not greater than 3% of GDP (Hochreiter, Korinek, & Siklos, 2003). Thus, like the first approach, this methodology mainly depends on descriptive measures instead of an econometric background.…”
Section: Literature Overviewmentioning
confidence: 99%