2014
DOI: 10.1111/1911-3846.12055
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Reputational Costs of Tax Avoidance

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2

Citation Types

7
195
1
35

Year Published

2014
2014
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 360 publications
(260 citation statements)
references
References 63 publications
7
195
1
35
Order By: Relevance
“…Dyreng, Hanlon, and Maydew (2008), for instance, provide evidence that firms' effective tax rates (ETRs) differ considerably and a quarter of the firms in their sample persistently pay taxes in excess of the statutory U.S. corporate tax rate. In accounting research, the term "undersheltering puzzle" was coined for this phenomenon (Gallemore, Maydew, and Thornock 2014, Hanlon and Heitzman 2010, Desai and Dharmapala 2006, Weisbach 2002. As the causes of the undersheltering puzzle are yet not entirely clear (Hanlon and Heitzman 2010), we examine whether and under which conditions heuristics lead to biases in tax-planning decisions that result in economically suboptimal decisions.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Dyreng, Hanlon, and Maydew (2008), for instance, provide evidence that firms' effective tax rates (ETRs) differ considerably and a quarter of the firms in their sample persistently pay taxes in excess of the statutory U.S. corporate tax rate. In accounting research, the term "undersheltering puzzle" was coined for this phenomenon (Gallemore, Maydew, and Thornock 2014, Hanlon and Heitzman 2010, Desai and Dharmapala 2006, Weisbach 2002. As the causes of the undersheltering puzzle are yet not entirely clear (Hanlon and Heitzman 2010), we examine whether and under which conditions heuristics lead to biases in tax-planning decisions that result in economically suboptimal decisions.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…We acknowledge that tax-minimizing behavior in reality does not necessarily imply economically optimal results. For instance firms differ in their financial reporting costs of tax planning (e.g., Frank, Lynch, andRego 2009, Badertscher, Philips, Pinco, and, regulatory costs of tax planning (e.g., Mills, Nutter, and Schwab 2013), or reputational costs of tax planning (e.g., Gallemore et al 2014) which implies different levels of economically optimal tax planning across firms. We neglect these aspects in our experimental setting to isolate the causal effect of tax-rate and tax-base effects on decision-making.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Consistent with the concern about providing a roadmap for taxing authorities, Abernathy, Davenport, and Rapley (2013) show a negative market reaction to the IRS's initial announcement regarding Schedule UTP, a required annual report detailing FIN 48 information. 7 While Graham et al (2014) document managers' belief of reputational costs related to tax avoidance, empirical evidence has not supported those views (Austin and Wilson 2015;Gallemore, Maydew, and Thornock 2014). 8 It is possible that high ETR firms may be viewed as underinvesting and would therefore want to lower ETR by accruing UTB interest and penalties outside of the tax expense.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The COLI shelter was the subject of unflattering coverage in the media, including the Wall Street Journal, which identified the companies that engaged in COLI alongside pictures of their actual deceased employees. COLI shelters are, therefore, an example of a tax avoidance strategy that many viewed as particularly aggressive and that resulted in adverse scrutiny for firms that engaged in them, see Gallemore et al (2014), p. 1106. 21 The OTSA was established to combat the rise of tax shelters in the late 1990s.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%