2003
DOI: 10.3386/w9586
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Retirement-Consumption Puzzle: Anticipated and Actual Declines in Spending at Retirement

Abstract: The simple one-good model of life-cycle consumption requires "consumption smoothing." However, British and U.S. households apparently reduce consumption at retirement and the reduction cannot be explained by the life-cycle model. An interpretation is that retirees are surprised by the inadequacy of resources. This interpretation challenges the life-cycle model where consumers are forward looking. However, data on anticipated consumption changes at retirement and on realized consumption changes following retire… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

5
55
2

Year Published

2006
2006
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
4
3

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 119 publications
(62 citation statements)
references
References 12 publications
5
55
2
Order By: Relevance
“…Third, among those with unfulfilled work expectations, the evidence points to the arrival of positive news about financial position after retirement (though not driven by the stock market gains) and/or negative news about health. These results complement evidence from studies of consumption behavior that suggest actual retirement turns out better than expected for most people (Forni 1999 ; Hurd and Rohwedder 2003; Mastrogiacomo 2003). Fourth, among the minority with unfulfilled expectations of leisure, the evidence points to the arrival of negative news about preferences for retirement leisure, rather than negative news about financial position.…”
Section: Discussionsupporting
confidence: 82%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Third, among those with unfulfilled work expectations, the evidence points to the arrival of positive news about financial position after retirement (though not driven by the stock market gains) and/or negative news about health. These results complement evidence from studies of consumption behavior that suggest actual retirement turns out better than expected for most people (Forni 1999 ; Hurd and Rohwedder 2003; Mastrogiacomo 2003). Fourth, among the minority with unfulfilled expectations of leisure, the evidence points to the arrival of negative news about preferences for retirement leisure, rather than negative news about financial position.…”
Section: Discussionsupporting
confidence: 82%
“… 1 A growing literature has examined whether such shocks can explain the seemingly “irrational” drops in consumption spending after retirement known as the retirement-consumption puzzle (Banks, Blundell, and Tanner 1998; Haider and Stephens 2004; Hurd and Rohwedder 2003; Smith 2004). …”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In this case household consumption should be constant over time and not change at retirement (HAI-DER;STEPHENS JR., 2007). However, several studies have founded evidences which challenges the implications of LCPIT showing that consumption tends to decrease at retirement (HAMERMESH, 1984;FAIR;DOMINGUEZ, 1991;BANKS;BLUNDELL;TANNER, 1998;BERNHEIM;SKINNER;WEINBERG, 2001;HURD;ROHWEDDER, 2003;SCHWERDT, 2005;HAIDER;STEPHENS JR., 2007;BAT-TISTIN et al, 2009;LI;CHI;WU, 2015).…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The explanation for this phenomenon would be that the marginal utility of consumption, and not consumption itself, would be smoothed over time, so that changes in family size, number of workers (economically active individuals), mortality or population aging may adjust the marginal utility consumption and cause consumption to fall at advanced ages. Furthermore, the reduction in consumption could also be explained by limitations in households' knowledge to forecast their correct permanent income and by the substitution effect between consumption and leisure which tends to increase over the time (HURD;ROHWEDDER, 2003;SMITH, 2004).…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation