2009
DOI: 10.1007/s11079-009-9125-9
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The Small Open-Economy New Keynesian Phillips Curve: Empirical Evidence and Implied Inflation Dynamics

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

2
37
3
1

Year Published

2011
2011
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
9

Relationship

1
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 54 publications
(43 citation statements)
references
References 29 publications
2
37
3
1
Order By: Relevance
“…This flatness is a well-known finding for many economies, whether the model estimated is a closed or open economy model -see e.g. Gali and Gertler (1999) for US, Mihailov, Rumler, and Scharler (2011) for Poland, Hungary, Slovakia, Latvia, Lithuania, Cyprus, Malta, Czech Republic, Slovenia, Bulgaria, where some estimates are even negative. Gali and Gertler (1999) argue that output gap is not proportional to real marginal cost, but real marginal cost better accounts for direct productivity gains on inflation, and so it should replace output gap in the Phillips curve.…”
mentioning
confidence: 64%
“…This flatness is a well-known finding for many economies, whether the model estimated is a closed or open economy model -see e.g. Gali and Gertler (1999) for US, Mihailov, Rumler, and Scharler (2011) for Poland, Hungary, Slovakia, Latvia, Lithuania, Cyprus, Malta, Czech Republic, Slovenia, Bulgaria, where some estimates are even negative. Gali and Gertler (1999) argue that output gap is not proportional to real marginal cost, but real marginal cost better accounts for direct productivity gains on inflation, and so it should replace output gap in the Phillips curve.…”
mentioning
confidence: 64%
“…They estimate the NKPC for 12 NMS (within the 2004 and 2007 enlargements), repeating the exact same empirical exercise as in Mihailov, Rumler and Scharler (2011a). Their results strongly point out the superiority of the original Galí and Monacelli (2005) model, which also enables the comparison of the relative importance of domestic factors (output gap) and foreign determinants (terms of trade) in explaining the inflation generating process.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 87%
“…One of the rare empirical studies of that kind is Mihailov, Rumler and Scharler (2011a), who make an effort to estimate the New Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) for 10 OECD countries using the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM). The authors start from the Galí and Monacelli (2005) open-economy NKPC model (comprising inflation expectations, output gap and the effective terms of trade vis-à-vis the rest of the world), and consider several alternative model specifications.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Most of the existing empirical studies are based on extended Phillips curve models, eg Ball (2006), Borio and Filardo (2007), Pehnelt (2007), Ihrig et al (2010), Guerrieri et al (2010) and Mihailov et al (2011). One theoretical weakness of the type of Phillips curve models is the absence of explicitly specified long-run disequilibrium effect on the inflation dynamics.…”
Section: Modelling Strategy and Data Issuesmentioning
confidence: 99%