2017
DOI: 10.1016/j.jeem.2016.10.004
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The social costs of second-best policies: Evidence from agricultural GHG mitigation

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
2
1

Citation Types

0
13
0

Year Published

2017
2017
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 14 publications
(13 citation statements)
references
References 65 publications
0
13
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The empirical application covers a large and diverse agricultural sector. This contrasts with previous studies of GHG mitigation in agriculture that have focused on narrower areas and/or a limited set of activities and mitigation options (Dakpo et al, 2016;Garnache et al, 2017;Pellerin et al, 2017).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 65%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The empirical application covers a large and diverse agricultural sector. This contrasts with previous studies of GHG mitigation in agriculture that have focused on narrower areas and/or a limited set of activities and mitigation options (Dakpo et al, 2016;Garnache et al, 2017;Pellerin et al, 2017).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 65%
“…3 The resulting limitation of inter-sectoral flexibility raises concerns about the possibility of meeting the ambitious EU mitigation targets in a cost-effective manner (Tol, 2009;De Cara and Vermont, 2011;European Environment Agency, 2017b). Second, agricultural GHG emissions result from a large number of heterogeneous farms, which makes monitoring costly (Garnache et al, 2017), a fact that has been used as a justification for excluding agricultural GHG emissions from the scope of climate policy in Europe (Ancev, 2011). Third, many provisions in the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) are already based on a differentiated treatment of small and large farms.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…While direct incentives such as pollution taxes would be more efficient instruments, they might not be feasible due to the impossibility to reliably attribute pollution to a particular source. This second-best feature is well-known to the literatures on GHG emissions from agriculture and forestry (e.g., Lubowski et al (2006); Garnache et al (2016)), water pollution from agricultural nutrient runoffs (e.g., Wu et al (2004); Rabotyagov et al (2014a)), or tailpipe emissions from vehicles (e.g., Fullerton and West (2002); Mérel et al (2014a)).…”
Section: Proposed Solutionmentioning
confidence: 77%
“…In other contexts where two actions may be taken together or in isolation, ki would take on three values: one for each single action and the third one for the combination of both. This reasoning also extends to sets of N continuous actions as in Kim and Langpap (2015) or Garnache et al (2016), as one can always map a subset of R N into R. The assumption that the functions ci be increasing and convex, although admittedly restrictive, ensures that second-best incentives lead to well-defined behavioral responses. Relaxing the convexity assumption, or allowing for a fixed cost of taking action, would lead to discontinuities in the behavioral responses to second-best incentives.…”
Section: Theoretical Frameworkmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation