2015
DOI: 10.1016/j.enpol.2015.03.009
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

The stuttering energy transition in Germany: Wind energy policy and feed-in tariff lock-in

Abstract: This article aims to examine whether the formulation of specific low carbon policy such as the feed-in tariff for wind energy in Germany can partly be a barrier to a comprehensive energy transition (Energiewende). Despite their short and medium-term success, these policies could create a long-term lock-in if they are formulated in a way that leads to a stagnation of systems innovation. The research finds that while the share of wind energy has increased rapidly over time, the feed-in-tariff and other low carbo… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
37
0

Year Published

2015
2015
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
6
1
1

Relationship

2
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 80 publications
(37 citation statements)
references
References 22 publications
0
37
0
Order By: Relevance
“…Germany's wind energy market has been growing continuously since the mid-1990s (BWE, 2012;IEA, 2013). The market shares of wind firms in Germany are as follows: about 60% Enercon, 20% Vestas, 10% REpower, 4% Nordex, 2% Bard, remaining 4%: others, including e.n.o., Vensys, Siemens and AREVA Nordensvard and Urban, 2015).…”
Section: Key Trends and Characteristics In The Eumentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Germany's wind energy market has been growing continuously since the mid-1990s (BWE, 2012;IEA, 2013). The market shares of wind firms in Germany are as follows: about 60% Enercon, 20% Vestas, 10% REpower, 4% Nordex, 2% Bard, remaining 4%: others, including e.n.o., Vensys, Siemens and AREVA Nordensvard and Urban, 2015).…”
Section: Key Trends and Characteristics In The Eumentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Therefore, institutions also change, but at a given time they keep their restrictive nature, as the rules of the game and norms are fixed for some time, preventing actors from seeing beyond the frame. Institutional lock-in becomes an issue when an institution becomes inflexible and continues to restrict the consideration of other alternatives (Nordensvärd and Urban 2015). By limiting the consideration of other options, institutional lock-in leads to the use of sub-optimal policies even though alternative policies may be available (Cantarelli et al 2010;Geels 2011;North 1990).…”
Section: Institutional Lock-inmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Watanabe (2009, 2010) discussed an innovation management approach for renewable energy deployment from the perspective of network externality and lock-in. Nordensvärd and Urban (2015) examined the specific low carbon policy such as feed-in tariff for wind energy in Germany can partly be a barrier to a comprehensive energy transition.…”
Section: A Model Of Energy Technology Adoption With Network Externalitymentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Take a concrete example, even if China has launched initiatives to deploy the promising RET on a large scale, this largest energy consuming country that specialized in energy-intensive manufacturing still has a large stock of old and inefficient vintages of FET-based power plants that have expanded their installed base with an expected lifetime of several decades. As a result, not only does this lead to skyrocketing fossil energy uses in the short run, this FET-based installed network also comes with a formidable long-term carbon lock-in inertia in energy system that merits additional policy regulation beyond traditional price-based instruments like carbon pricing (Unruh and Carrillo-Hermosilla, 2006;Kalkuhl, 2012;Karlsson, 2012;Nordensvärd and Urban, 2015). Therefore, to create a level playing field that facilitates RET deployment, the conventional policy regimes based on the removal of cost gaps may not suffice.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation