2009
DOI: 10.1007/s11166-009-9073-1
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Time discounting: Declining impatience and interval effect

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
17
1

Year Published

2010
2010
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
5
3

Relationship

2
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 28 publications
(18 citation statements)
references
References 20 publications
0
17
1
Order By: Relevance
“…By contrast, the golden eggs model predicts that even fully rational consumers will exhibit asset-specific MPCs. 13 In the golden eggs model the current self is always endogenously liquidity constrained on the equilibrium path. So the MPC out of current cash flow is one.…”
Section: Asset-specific Mpcsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…By contrast, the golden eggs model predicts that even fully rational consumers will exhibit asset-specific MPCs. 13 In the golden eggs model the current self is always endogenously liquidity constrained on the equilibrium path. So the MPC out of current cash flow is one.…”
Section: Asset-specific Mpcsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Proposition 2 formalizes this claim. 13. Laibson [1994b] proposes another hyperbolic discounting model that generates some mental accounting behavior.…”
Section: Asset-specific Mpcsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…It is therefore important to examine the role of age-dependency of time-perception in intertemporal choice, in future behavioral economic studies. Moreover, it is known that there are some "anomalies" in intertemporal choice (e.g., hyperbolic discounting, sign effect, subadditive discounting, delay-speedup asymmetry, and interval effect) (Frederick, Shane, Loewenstein, & O'Donoghue, 2002;Kinari, Ohtake, & Tsutsui, 2009;Scholten & Read, 2010;Takahashi, 2009). Future studies in behavioral economics should examine whether these anomalies in intertemporal choice are related to socio-emotional status, age, and education.…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Subadditive discounting occurs when people are more impatient when the delay to an outcome is divided into subintervals than when it is undivided (e.g., Kinari, Ohtake and Tsutsui, 2009;McAlvanah, 2010;Read, 2001;Read and Roelofsma, 2003;Scholten and Read, 2006;. Reconsider the example for the delay effect discussed in the preceding section.…”
Section: Subadditive Discountingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Tests of the common difference effect serve as evidence for hyperbolic discounting, free from the confusion of subadditive discounting. However, existing evidence has shown a mixture of constant impatience (e.g., Halevy, 2015;Read, 2001), decreasing impatience or hyperbolic discounting (e.g., Bleichrodt, Gao and Rohde, 2016;Green, Myerson and Macaux, 2005;Kinari et al, 2009;Read and Read, 2004;Read and Roelofsma, 2003;Scholten and Read, 2006;Sopher and Sheth, 2006) and increasing impatience or antihyperbolic discounting (e.g., Attema et al, 2010Attema et al, , 2016Holcomb and Nelson, 1992;Read, Olivola and Hardisty, in press;Sayman and Öncüler, 2009).…”
Section: The Common Difference Effect (And Its Reversal)mentioning
confidence: 99%