2017
DOI: 10.3982/ecta13960
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Uncertainty Shocks in a Model of Effective Demand

Abstract: THIS SECTION PROVIDES additional details on the data construction and estimation procedure for the empirical evidence from Section 2 of the main text. We estimate our baseline VAR using data on the VXO, GDP, consumption, investment, hours worked, the GDP deflator, the M2 money stock, and the Wu and Xia (2016) shadow rate. To match the concept in the model, we measure consumption in the data as the sum of non-durable and services consumption. Then, we use the sum of consumer durables and private fixed investmen… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
4
1

Citation Types

20
238
3

Year Published

2020
2020
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 614 publications
(261 citation statements)
references
References 64 publications
20
238
3
Order By: Relevance
“…2 The basic neoclassical model is not particularly conducive to studying the effects of second moment shocks. For small values of household risk aversion the effects of second moment shocks are negligible in the basic neoclassical model, while for high levels of risk aversion (as in Basu and Bundick, 2012 ) the effects are not negligible, but then investment and consumption do not comove in response to these shocks -a result which is at odds with the data where there exists strong comovement between consumption and investment. Basu and Bundick (2012) provide an explanation for why the incorrect comovement occurs in the basic neoclassical model.…”
Section: Introductioncontrasting
confidence: 48%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…2 The basic neoclassical model is not particularly conducive to studying the effects of second moment shocks. For small values of household risk aversion the effects of second moment shocks are negligible in the basic neoclassical model, while for high levels of risk aversion (as in Basu and Bundick, 2012 ) the effects are not negligible, but then investment and consumption do not comove in response to these shocks -a result which is at odds with the data where there exists strong comovement between consumption and investment. Basu and Bundick (2012) provide an explanation for why the incorrect comovement occurs in the basic neoclassical model.…”
Section: Introductioncontrasting
confidence: 48%
“…For small values of household risk aversion the effects of second moment shocks are negligible in the basic neoclassical model, while for high levels of risk aversion (as in Basu and Bundick, 2012 ) the effects are not negligible, but then investment and consumption do not comove in response to these shocks -a result which is at odds with the data where there exists strong comovement between consumption and investment. Basu and Bundick (2012) provide an explanation for why the incorrect comovement occurs in the basic neoclassical model. It should be noted here that many models in this literature inherit the negative comovement problem and are either unable to solve it or have to appeal to nominal rigidities or additional real rigidities to generate comovements between consumption and investment.…”
Section: Introductioncontrasting
confidence: 48%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…First of all, the countercyclical pattern of the markup is also assumed by Basu and Bundick (2012) within an exogenous driven business cycle model. 8 In the second place, (average) fixed costs fall as output expands and this relaxes the borrowing constraints disproportionately more.…”
Section: Credit Constraints and Markupsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…That literature is mixed on the impact of volatility shocks. Some papers find that higher volatility reduces output (Alexopoulos and Cohen, 2009;Basu and Bundick, 2014;Bloom, 2009;Bloom et al, 2014), while others report little or no impact (Bachmann and Bayer, 2013;Chugh, 2013).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 95%