2018
DOI: 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2018.03.007
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Vertical licensing, input pricing, and entry

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
2
1

Citation Types

1
12
0

Year Published

2020
2020
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
6
1

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 17 publications
(13 citation statements)
references
References 57 publications
1
12
0
Order By: Relevance
“…In light of this, U has incentives to prevent the MNE's entry only when it is through greenfield investment and its bargaining power is not sufficiently high or final products are too close substitutes. U could do so by lobbying with the host country's government so that stricter restrictions and higher costs are imposed on greenfield investment, by integrating forward and (partially) foreclosing the MNE (Bakaouka and Milliou ) or by establishing its own downstream firm and intensifying downstream competition.…”
Section: Welfare Implicationsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In light of this, U has incentives to prevent the MNE's entry only when it is through greenfield investment and its bargaining power is not sufficiently high or final products are too close substitutes. U could do so by lobbying with the host country's government so that stricter restrictions and higher costs are imposed on greenfield investment, by integrating forward and (partially) foreclosing the MNE (Bakaouka and Milliou ) or by establishing its own downstream firm and intensifying downstream competition.…”
Section: Welfare Implicationsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Most of the literature on technology licensing analyzes various aspects of licensing in one-tier markets, such as the choice among licensing fee and royalties (e.g., Kamien and Tauman, 1986, Muto, 1993, Wang, 1998, the use of licensing for entry deterrence (Gallini, 1984), the impact of licensing on innovation (e.g., Gallini and Winter, 1985), and the choice among licensing and merger (Fauli-Oller and Sandonis, 2003). Our paper is closely related to the limited literature that examines licensing in vertically related markets, such as Mukherjee (2003), Arya and Mittendorf (2006), Mukherjee and Ray (2007), Rey and Salant (2012), Bakaouka and Milliou (2018). This literature shows that horizontal licensing in the downstream market is pro…table only if it enhances competition in the upstream market (Mukherjee, 2003) or if it creates a weak rival (Arya and Mittendorf, 2006).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 61%
“…One of them, without loss of generality …rm 1, considers licensing its input production technology to an external …rm, …rm S, for a …xed licensing fee, F 0. 8 When licensing takes place, the licensee (…rm S) is in the position to produce the licensor's (…rm 1's) input at marginal cost c. 9 The knowledge that …rm S acquires through licensing regarding the production of the …nal good's core input could also allow it to produce the …nal good. Thus, licensing could cause …rm S's entry into the …nal goods market too.…”
Section: The Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 2 more Smart Citations