2010
DOI: 10.1093/poq/nfq001
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Wars, Presidents, and Popularity: The Political Cost(s) of War Re-Examined

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1

Citation Types

0
33
0

Year Published

2011
2011
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
8
2

Relationship

0
10

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 40 publications
(33 citation statements)
references
References 52 publications
0
33
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The literature on vote and popularity functions, for example, clearly illustrates that taxation has a significant political cost for incumbents in the sense that it reduces their popularity or re-election odds (e.g., Niskanen, 1975;Peltzman, 1992;Vermeir and Heyndels, 2006;Geys and Vermeir, 2008a, b;Geys, 2010). This desire for public goods but reluctance to pay for them suggests that an efficient provision of public goods and services -understood in terms of a maximum amount of public good provision at given (fiscal) costs (or 'value for money') -is likely to win voters' hearts.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The literature on vote and popularity functions, for example, clearly illustrates that taxation has a significant political cost for incumbents in the sense that it reduces their popularity or re-election odds (e.g., Niskanen, 1975;Peltzman, 1992;Vermeir and Heyndels, 2006;Geys and Vermeir, 2008a, b;Geys, 2010). This desire for public goods but reluctance to pay for them suggests that an efficient provision of public goods and services -understood in terms of a maximum amount of public good provision at given (fiscal) costs (or 'value for money') -is likely to win voters' hearts.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…On the costs side of the ledger, most prior scholarship has focused almost exclusively on the critical importance of combat casualties in these calculations (Althaus et al, 2012;Gartner, 2008;Gartner and Segura, 1998;Kriner and Shen, 2010;Larson, 1996;Mueller, 1973;Voeten and Brewer, 2006). In contrast, comparatively few studies have examined how the financial costs of military action affect public support for war (although see Berinsky, 2007;Geys, 2010). Even fewer scholars have examined how the instrument chosen by political leaders to raise the requisite capital-be it varying forms of taxation or deficit spending-influences support for war.…”
Section: Taxation and Public Support For Warmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Indeed, there is a significant political cost of taxation in the sense that it reduces politicians' popularity or re-election odds (e.g., Niskanen, 1975;Peltzman, 1992;Vermeir and Heyndels, 2006;Geys and Vermeir, 2008a, b;Geys, 2010). Yet, the public goods provided as a result of tax revenues are commonly appreciated.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%