2018
DOI: 10.1016/j.jesp.2018.03.006
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

What's next? Disentangling availability from representativeness using binary decision tasks

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
8
0

Year Published

2020
2020
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

1
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 10 publications
(8 citation statements)
references
References 28 publications
0
8
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The availability, affect, and representativeness heuristics are conceptually distinct and represent distinct mechanisms (i.e., reported amount of negative affect for the affect heuristic, perceived similarity for the representativeness heuristic, and availability in memory for the availability heuristic; Finucane et al, 2000;Tversky & Kahneman, 1973, 1974. However, few studies have examined whether the conceptual distinctions translate to empirical distinctions (but see Braga et al, 2018;Efendić, 2021;Keller et al, 2006). Disentangling the heuristics empirically could help identify which heuristic drives judgments and decisions more than others.…”
Section: Heuristics and Decision-makingmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The availability, affect, and representativeness heuristics are conceptually distinct and represent distinct mechanisms (i.e., reported amount of negative affect for the affect heuristic, perceived similarity for the representativeness heuristic, and availability in memory for the availability heuristic; Finucane et al, 2000;Tversky & Kahneman, 1973, 1974. However, few studies have examined whether the conceptual distinctions translate to empirical distinctions (but see Braga et al, 2018;Efendić, 2021;Keller et al, 2006). Disentangling the heuristics empirically could help identify which heuristic drives judgments and decisions more than others.…”
Section: Heuristics and Decision-makingmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Such procedures can sacrifice generalizability to the broader population for experimental control. Consequently, some research on heuristics in real‐world health decision‐making (rather than hypothetical scenarios) has instead measured people's responses to heuristic cues (i.e., survey items that assess endorsement of concepts related to heuristics, such as the amount of affect or the ease of retrieving relevant instances from memory) and correlated them with risk judgments (e.g., Gerend, Aiken, & West, 2004; Gerend, Aiken, West, & Erchull, 2004; Greening et al., 1996; McDowell et al., 2013, but see counterexamples Braga et al., 2018; Hertwig et al., 2005; Pachur et al., 2012).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The gambler's fallacy starts to show up in elementary school, and peaks among college students (Bogartz, 1965 ; Chiesi & Primi, 2009 ; Derks & Paclisanu, 1967 ; Estes, 1962 ; Craig & Meyers, 1963 ). People also take longer to predict reversal than repetition, and are more likely to predict repetition than reversal under time constraints or cognitive load (Braga, Ferreira, Sherman, Mata, Jacinto, & Ferreira, 2018 ; Diener & Thompson, 1985 ; Militana, Wolfson, & Cleaveland, 2010 ; Tyszka, Markiewicz, Kubińska, Gawryluk, & Zielonka, 2017 ).…”
Section: Theoretical and Empirical Context For The Present Researchmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Instead of clearly specifying identical base rates for each generator, experimenters either rely on participants’ prior beliefs (e.g., that a fair coin has a stationary .50 base rate, or that a basketball player performs at an unspecified, perhaps “typical,” rate), or they provide base rate information that may be interpreted as stationary for random devices, but shifting for intentional actors. For example, Braga and colleagues ( 2018 ) compared predictions for coin flips to those for athletic performances. The authors provided explicit information that the coin was fair (stationary .50 base rate), and that flipping the coin was a random process.…”
Section: Theoretical and Empirical Context For The Present Researchmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…The gambler's fallacy starts to show up in elementary school, and peaks among college students (Bogartz, 1965;Chiesi & Primi, 2009;Derks & Paclisanu, 1967;Estes, 1962;Craig & Meyers, 1963). People also take longer to predict reversal than repetition, and are more likely to predict repetition than reversal under time constraint or cognitive load (Braga, Ferreira, Sherman, Mata, Jacinto, & Ferreira, 2018;Diener & Thompson, 1985;Militana, Wolfson, & Cleaveland, 2010;Tyszka, Markiewicz, Kubińska, Gawryluk, & Zielonka, 2017).…”
Section: Theoretical Accounts Of Prediction Behaviormentioning
confidence: 99%