AEA Randomized Controlled Trials 2016
DOI: 10.1257/rct.1169
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Why Don’t the Poor Save More? Evidence from Health Savings Experiments

Abstract: for research assistance in the field. All errors are our own. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peerreviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications.

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

19
188
2
5

Year Published

2016
2016
2021
2021

Publication Types

Select...
8

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 132 publications
(214 citation statements)
references
References 16 publications
19
188
2
5
Order By: Relevance
“…Savings programs with commitment mechanisms often entail mental accounting methods, such as “labeling,” which segregates sums of money for specific goals, decreases fungibility, and thereby protects savings from the requests of friends or family (Ashraf et al., ; Dupas & Robinson, ). As cultural norms in sub‐Saharan Africa may obligate individuals to give what is readily available (Mpiira et al., ; Platteau, ), the mental allocations of funds through labeling or more formalized savings commitment devices, such as timed deposits or conditional withdrawals, can decrease this sense of “availability” (Ashraf et al., ; Dupas & Robinson, ) and help foster routinized savings.…”
Section: Situating Savings Within a Behavioral Economics Contextmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Savings programs with commitment mechanisms often entail mental accounting methods, such as “labeling,” which segregates sums of money for specific goals, decreases fungibility, and thereby protects savings from the requests of friends or family (Ashraf et al., ; Dupas & Robinson, ). As cultural norms in sub‐Saharan Africa may obligate individuals to give what is readily available (Mpiira et al., ; Platteau, ), the mental allocations of funds through labeling or more formalized savings commitment devices, such as timed deposits or conditional withdrawals, can decrease this sense of “availability” (Ashraf et al., ; Dupas & Robinson, ) and help foster routinized savings.…”
Section: Situating Savings Within a Behavioral Economics Contextmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Relative to a control group not offered the commitment savings product, those offered the commitment account had bank balances that were 82% higher 12 months later. Corroborating work on commitment savings products in other countries includes Gugerty (2007), Ashraf et al (2011), Brune et al (2011), and Dupas & Robinson (2013). This research provides a rationalization for restrictions on the ability to access retirement savings account balances before reaching retirement age.…”
Section: Behaviorally Informed Policy Tools To Help Agents Executementioning
confidence: 92%
“…Households in low-income contexts are particularly vulnerable: smoothing mechanisms like savings, credit, insurance, and informal financial networks often function poorly in these contexts (Dupas and Robinson, 2013; Kochar, 1999, 2004; Pande and Burgess, 2005; Paxson, 1992; Townsend, 1994). Moreover, income-generating activities within the household are often intertwined: parents and children work together on family farms, and extended family members pool resources in business (Adhvaryu et al, 2013; Benjamin, 1992; Dercon and Krishnan, 2000).…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%