2011
DOI: 10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.10.008
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Why mutual funds “underperform”☆

Abstract: I propose a parsimonious model that reproduces the negative risk-adjusted performance of actively managed equity mutual funds. In the model, a fund manager can generate state-dependent active returns at a disutility. Negative expected performance and mutual fund investing simultaneously arise in equilibrium because the active return the fund manager generates covaries positively with a component of the pricing kernel that the performance measure omits, consistent with recent empirical evidence. Using data on U… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

24
148
5

Year Published

2013
2013
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
8
2

Relationship

0
10

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 286 publications
(177 citation statements)
references
References 60 publications
24
148
5
Order By: Relevance
“…It is therefore likely that persistently poor performance by some funds also requires an assumption of "frictions" in the ability to switch from poorly performing to potential winner funds. Other explanations of long-term negative performance include pure inertia, influences of broker and manager advertising and tax considerations (Gruber, 1996) or negative performance as a payoff for countercyclical performance (Glode, 2009) or that investors buy and sell actual index funds at the wrong time, and passive indices do not reflect this (Savov 2009 …”
Section: Methodology and Performancementioning
confidence: 99%
“…It is therefore likely that persistently poor performance by some funds also requires an assumption of "frictions" in the ability to switch from poorly performing to potential winner funds. Other explanations of long-term negative performance include pure inertia, influences of broker and manager advertising and tax considerations (Gruber, 1996) or negative performance as a payoff for countercyclical performance (Glode, 2009) or that investors buy and sell actual index funds at the wrong time, and passive indices do not reflect this (Savov 2009 …”
Section: Methodology and Performancementioning
confidence: 99%
“…We show that by using a conditional past performance measure to focus on time periods when information-to-noise ratio is high, we can obtain a much stronger performance forecasting power. Second, our paper contributes to the literature that examines time-varying asset return and fund performance predictability conditioning on market situations, including Ferson and Schadt (1996), Moskowitz (2000), Cooper, Gutierrez andHameed (2004), Fung, Hsieh, Naik, andRamadorai (2008), Glode (2011), Kosowski (2011), Kacperczyk, Van Nieuwerburgh, andVeldkamp (2013a, b), De Souza and Lynch (2012), Glode, Hollifield, Kacperczyk, and Kogan (2012). In particular, Cooper, Gutierrez and Hameed (2004) and Glode, Hollifield, Kacperczyk, and Kogan (2012) study return persistence for stocks and mutual funds, respectively, and find stronger persistence following periods of strong markets.…”
mentioning
confidence: 98%
“…Savov (2009) builds a noisy rational expectations model with wealth shocks to show that active funds and index funds are equally attractive as long as time-varying exposure is considered. Another model proposed by Glode (2011) also documents the active funds' signifi cant better realized performance in bad states of the economy than in good states. Pastor and Stambaugh (2012) rationalize this puzzle by the impact of slow Bayesian updating.…”
Section: Literature Reviewmentioning
confidence: 97%