Introduction A small revolution is going on in statistics today as the emphasis is slowly shifting from description to inference to decision-making. The newest branch of statistics, grouped generally under terms such as "statistical decision theory" or "Bayesian statistics", had its beginnings many years ago in ideas expounded by Bayes, with more recent contributions from Savage, Wald, Raiffa and Schlaifer. Rather than contradict, these new ideas extend "classical" statistics, particularly in the areas of significance tests and confidence-interval estimates, by introducing concepts of personal probabilities and economic gains and losses directly into the statistical calculations. These new approaches are quite powerful and also quite controversial. This paper will seek to illustrate some points of agreement and differences between the two approaches, with an illustration of the use of Bayesian statistics in a very simplified decision problem. An Example Decision Problem An oil company is considering an exploration program in a geologic region. Wells cost $250,000 each, and the firm believes that the exploration program will be approximately a breakeven proposition (or that the firm will earn its minimum rate of return) if at least 20 per cent of the wells are successful. This implies that "success" on any one well is defined for this firm as at least a present-value $1,250,000 well $1,250,000 (.20) = $250,000. For simplification only, this present value is assumed to be a constant. The variable is the success ratio P. Should the firm begin the drilling program? Success or failure depends on whether the unknown parameter P is less than, equal to, or greater than .20. The Classical Approach Two Hypotheses In classical statistical terms, the problem could be stated as a decision between two competing hypotheses on which evidence may be brought to bear: H(o): P greater than .20; and H(1): P less than .20.Actually, there are many possible values for P, ranging from 0 to 1.0, and the true value of P is unknown. The value P = .20 can be thought of as the breakeven value P(b) for which the firm would be about indifferent between drilling or not drilling. H(o) could be labeled the "null" hypothesis, inasmuch as rejection of this hypothesis when it is true may be regarded by this firm as more serious than acceptance of it when it is false. H(1), therefore, becomes the "alternate" hypothesis, incidentally, some operators might prefer to relabel these, feeling that drilling when P less than .20 is more serious, but most oil men probably feel that missing out on a potentially productive area is more serious than spending money on a nonproductive area. Errors Now if the firm rejects H, when it is actually true (in this case the firm abandons the program when, actually, it is potentially profitable), it is said to be an error of the "first kind", Type I. if the firm accepts H(o) when it is actually false (in this case, the firm spends money when the program is actually not profitable), then the firm is said to incur an error of the "second kind", Type II. This is set forth in Table 1.What shall the firm do? if no one in the organization is willing to express any feeling (probability) one way or another as to whether either of the two hypotheses is more likely to be true than the other, then the firm is in danger of the same fate as Buridan's ass who starved to death between two bales of hay because they were equidistant. Sampling to Formulate Decision Rules At this point, the classical statistician would probably suggest a sample, i.e., drill a few wells. And, based on the sample, the statistician would talk about an inference concerning the true value of P by choosing between the two hypotheses about this value. He generally would focus his attention on the choice between rejection and acceptance of the supposedly more serious null hypothesis. Of course, such acceptance or rejection does lead to a "terminal" action which, in this example, would either begin or not begin an expanded drilling program. TABLE 1 - STATE OF THE WORLD p .20 p .20 H(o): p .20 Correct Type II H(1): p .20 Type I Correct JPT P. 603^
The president of a major oil company was recently quoted in The Oil and Gas Journal, as saying that today's circumstances require every oil-company management to "face up to reality and begin making more hard-headed decisions" (italics mine) regarding its day-to-day operations and future capital investment policies. The reasons he cited were the slowed rate of growth in demand and overcapacity in nearly every phase of oil operations. Judging from similar remarks by others in the industry, it appears that the future success of the industry, and particularly, that of individual companies, is going to depend on wise courses of action, or as he puts it, "hardheaded decisions." I agree. In this paper, I want to talk about such hard headed decision making. What really is a decision? How does one go about collecting information, naming alternatives, assigning gains and losses from alternative actions, formulating criteria, selecting one action? It is difficult enough under conditions of relative simplicity and certainty, but when the decision is complex and the outcomes highly uncertain, the problem is compounded. DECISION PROCEDURES In such a situation, a decision maker generally follows one of three courses:Decides solely on the basis of intuition, judgment, hunch, seat of pants, experience, etc.. This is decision making as an art.Decides on the basis of simple, quick calculations and "reasonedjudgment." This is mixed art and scientific thinking.Decides on the basis of some fairly detailed and rigorous procedure, capturing as much information and judgment as possible in mathematical and statistical language so that it may be studied and manipulated by formallogic. The last decision procedure is what can be called hard-headed decision making. It is what academic people are referring to today as "decisiontheory."
scite is a Brooklyn-based organization that helps researchers better discover and understand research articles through Smart Citations–citations that display the context of the citation and describe whether the article provides supporting or contrasting evidence. scite is used by students and researchers from around the world and is funded in part by the National Science Foundation and the National Institute on Drug Abuse of the National Institutes of Health.
customersupport@researchsolutions.com
10624 S. Eastern Ave., Ste. A-614
Henderson, NV 89052, USA
This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.
Copyright © 2025 scite LLC. All rights reserved.
Made with 💙 for researchers
Part of the Research Solutions Family.