This article looks at the impact of Robert Parker's oenological grades on the so-called en primeur prices of young Bordeaux wines. The Parker grades are usually published in the spring of each year, before the wine prices are established. However, the wine grades for 2003 were published much later, in the autumn, after the determination of prices. This unusual reversal is exploited to estimate a Parker effect which we find to be, on average, worth 2.80 euros per bottle of wine. We also use gradespecific effects to predict what prices would have been had Parker attended the 2003 spring tasting. 14 This estimator is sometimes called the Ôdifference-in-differences estimatorÕ. This can be seen by considering the regression model Pis a time-specific component, g i a wine-specific component, and v i (t) a transitory shock with mean zero at each period. Specifically, g i may represent factors that are constant over the two years such as technology, natural endowments, and ranking, and d(t) gathers all factors that are common to all wines in year t such as weather conditions (although weather conditions may differ substantially from one place to another within the Bordeaux vineyard, thus varying with i, Lecocq and Visser (2006) show that these differences have very little impact on prices). Differencing, and using that D i (2003) ¼ 0 for all i, we get P i (2002)
The purpose of this paper is to measure the impact of Robert Parker's oenological grades on Bordeaux wine prices. We study their impact on the so-called en primeur wine prices, i.e., the prices determined by the chateau owners when the wines are still extremely young. The Parker grades are usually published in the spring of each year, before the wine prices are established. However, the wine grades attributed in 2003 have been published much later, in the autumn, after the determination of the prices. This unusual reversal is exploited to estimate a Parker effect. We find that, on average, the effect is equal to 2.80 euros per bottle of wine. We also estimate gradespecific effects, and use these estimates to predict what the prices would have been had Parker attended the spring tasting in 2003. (JEL Classification: C21, D89, L15). * We are grateful to Patrice Borda, Alan Duncan, Fabrice Etile\ Victor Ginsburgh, Sylvie Lambert, two anonymous referees, and participants at the VDQS conference (Dijon, 2004), the RES conference (Nottingham, 2005), the JMA meeting (Hammamet, 2005), and the EEA congress (Amsterdam, 2005), for their helpful comments and suggestions.
The market for "primeur" wine in the Bordeaux region allows producers to sell wine that is still in barrels. As with all experience goods, producers send quality signals to uninformed buyers. Using original data on Bordeaux wines, we show that the pricing behaviour of producers depends to a large extent on their reputation, and much less on short-term changes in quality (as measured by experts' grades). We also find that the primeur price has an informative role, since a 10 percent increase in primeur price leads to a 3 percent increase in prices on the market for bottled wine.Keywords: Bordeaux wine, experience good, panel data, quality signal, reputation. Suggested running head:The pricing of en primeur wine While writing this article, Héla Hadj Ali was working as a research fellow at INRA (National Institute for Research in Agriculture), Toulouse (France). Céline Nauges is a senior research fellow at INRA, Toulouse (France).The authors wish to thank Pierre Dubois, Valérie Meunier, Katrin Millock, Michel Simioni, Alban Thomas, Ian M. Sheldon (the editor), Michael Visser, and two anonymous reviewers for their useful comments and suggestions that materially improved the article. The usual caveats apply.-1 -Most food products can be classified as experience goods (Nelson 1970;1974) because their quality can rarely be ascertained before actual consumption.1 A substantial part of the theoretical literature dealing with experience goods has focused on sellers' activity to inform consumers in their purchases, particularly the role of signaling and reputation. Prices, advertising expenditure (Milgrom and Roberts 1986) and warranties (Grossman 1981) are textbook illustrations of how a monopolist can signal the high quality of his product in a game with asymmetric information. Shapiro (1983) emphasized the role of reputation in a perfectly competitive environment by describing how consumers form rational expectations on the quality of experience goods based on the quality of goods produced in the past.In the particular case of food products, producers often choose labeling as a signal of quality. Bureau and Valceschini (2003) showed that labeling helps promote differentiated products and allows small producers to benefit from a well-established collective reputation.More generally, the use of food labels is said to create the potential for price premia (Henneberry and Armbruster 2003).Quantitative measures of these "price premia" are quite rare, as well as, more generally, analyses of the pricing strategy and signaling activity of producers in markets for food products. This is especially the case when compared with hedonic studies that measure the consumers' assessment of food product attributes (see McCluskey and Loureiro 2003, for a review). This article contributes to the empirical literature on experience goods by analysing the pricing behaviour of wine producers from the well-known Bordeaux region in France.Original data on two markets (for "primeur" wine and for bottled wine) provide a unique opportunity to obt...
The market for "primeur" wine in the Bordeaux region allows producers to sell wine that is still in barrels. As with all experience goods, producers send quality signals to uninformed buyers. Using original data on Bordeaux wines, we show that the pricing behaviour of producers depends to a large extent on their reputation, and much less on short-term changes in quality (as measured by experts' grades). We also find that the primeur price has an informative role, since a 10 percent increase in primeur price leads to a 3 percent increase in prices on the market for bottled wine.
Oncherchedanscetarticleàexpliquerl’engouementrécentsuscitéparlesystèmedesventesenprimeursurlemarchédes grandsvins.ÀpartirdedonnéesdeprixconcernantdesvinsdeBordeaux,onanalyselaplus-valueréaliséedèslapremière cotation du vin après sa sortie en primeur. On montre qu’un investissement dans le vin primeur (entre 1995 et 1999) a procuré des rendements significativement meilleurs que les investissements sur le marché boursier traditionnel. Cette analyse met également en lumière la spécificité du marché des cinq grands crus.
scite is a Brooklyn-based organization that helps researchers better discover and understand research articles through Smart Citations–citations that display the context of the citation and describe whether the article provides supporting or contrasting evidence. scite is used by students and researchers from around the world and is funded in part by the National Science Foundation and the National Institute on Drug Abuse of the National Institutes of Health.
customersupport@researchsolutions.com
10624 S. Eastern Ave., Ste. A-614
Henderson, NV 89052, USA
This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.
Copyright © 2024 scite LLC. All rights reserved.
Made with 💙 for researchers
Part of the Research Solutions Family.