Hailed by its exponents as a unifying paradigm for social theory and dismissed by its critiques as an imperialistic intrusion into sociology coming from neoclassical economics, rational choice theory is one of the most significant and controversial developments in contemporary sociological theory. This report reconsiders the degree of adequacy of rational choice theory for modern sociology. The report focuses its attention on the concept of rationality in rational choice theory. The major assumption or implication of modern rational choice theory, just as the old utilitarianism and neoclassical economics, is the status of human rationality as ipso facto utilitarian-economic rationality, namely the maximization of utility, profit or wealth, and alternatively the minimization of costs and other `disutilities'. This assumption is re-examined in this report. The point of departure of this examination is the argument that rational choice broadly understood is not necessarily utilitarian-economic rationality, namely utility- or profit-optimizing behavior.
The article reconsiders the generalization of neoclassical economics by modern rational choice theory. Hence, it reexamines the possible theoretical grounds or lack thereof within neoclassical economics for economic imperialism implied in much of rational choice theory. Some indicative instances of rational choice theory's generalization of neoclassical economics are reviewed. The main portion of the article addresses the question as to whether neoclassical economics allows its generalization in rational choice theory and thus legitimizes economic imperialism. Presented are a number of pertinent theoretical reasons why neoclassical economics does not fully justify its generalization into rational choice as a general social theory, particularly into an overarching economic approach to social action and society. Also discussed are some theoretical implications of the rational choice generalization of neoclassical economics. The main contribution of the article is to detect lack of a strong theoretical rationale in much of neoclassical economics for rational choice theory's manifest or latent economic imperialism.This article reconsiders the current uses of classical and neoclassical traditions in economics to legitimize a certain approach, such as rational choice, in contemporary sociological theory and elsewhere~political science, for example!. With the rise of sociological rational choice theory~Hechter and Kanazawa 1997; Kiser and Hechter 1998!, or rational action theory for sociology~Goldthorpe 1998!, as one of the "most influential theoretical developments of our time"~Somers 1998!, many of its advocates believe that they make a "rational choice of theory"~Abell 1992! by adopting and applying with slight modifications the basic notions of the economic approach to human behavior~Becker 1976!, as putatively rooted in neo-classical economics. Such notions include atomistic individuals free from complex interdependencies, the pursuit of pure self-interest~construed as happiness!, farsighted rationality and accurate cost-benefit calculation, market equilibrium and/or~the Pareto! optimum, parametric individual preferences/values, technologies, social institutions and cultures, consistent maximization of profit~producers! and utility~con-sumers!, free and perfect competition, a laissez-faire government, full knowledge and complete information, etc.Arguably, the outcome has been sociological rational choice theory's generalization of neoclassical economics 1~R ambo 1999! beyond the original realm of the market into nonmarket domains. This represents a generalization and extension of the basic assumptions and concepts of neoclassical economics from the economy to society. Specifically, such
scite is a Brooklyn-based organization that helps researchers better discover and understand research articles through Smart Citations–citations that display the context of the citation and describe whether the article provides supporting or contrasting evidence. scite is used by students and researchers from around the world and is funded in part by the National Science Foundation and the National Institute on Drug Abuse of the National Institutes of Health.