This paper is split in three parts:¯rst, we use labeled trade data to exhibit how market participants' decisions depend on liquidity imbalance; then, we develop a stochastic control framework where agents monitor limit orders, by exploiting liquidity imbalance, to reduce adverse selection. For limit orders, we need optimal strategies essentially to¯nd a balance between fast execution and avoiding adverse selection: if the price has chances to go down, the probability to be¯lled is high, but it is better to wait a little more to get a better price. In a third part, we show how the added value of exploiting liquidity imbalance is eroded by latency: being able to predict future liquidity consuming°ows is of less use if you do not have enough time to cancel and reinsert your limit orders. There is thus a rationale for market makers to be as fast as possible to reduce adverse selection. Latency costs of our limit order driven strategy can be measured numerically.To authors' knowledge, this paper is the¯rst to make the connection between empirical evidences, a stochastic framework for limit orders including adverse selection, and the cost of latency. Our work is a¯rst step to shed light on the role played by latency and adverse selection in optimal limit order placement.
We consider an agent who needs to buy (or sell) a relatively small amount of asset over some fixed short time interval. We work at the highest frequency meaning that we wish to find the optimal tactic to execute our quantity using limit orders, market orders and cancellations. To solve the agent's control problem, we build an order book model and optimize an expected utility function based on our price impact. We derive the equations satisfied by the optimal strategy and solve them numerically. Moreover, we show that our optimal tactic enables us to outperform significantly naive execution strategies.
We model the behavior of three agent classes acting dynamically in a limit order book of a financial asset. Namely, we consider market makers (MM), high-frequency trading (HFT) firms, and institutional brokers (IB). Given a prior dynamic of the order book, similar to the one considered in the Queue-Reactive models [12,18,19], the MM and the HFT define their trading strategy by optimizing the expected utility of terminal wealth, while the IB has a prescheduled task to sell or buy many shares of the considered asset. We derive the variational partial differential equations that characterize the value functions of the MM and HFT and explain how almost optimal control can be deduced from them. We then provide a first illustration of the interactions that can take place between these different market participants by simulating the dynamic of an order book in which each of them plays his own (optimal) strategy. . D. Evangelista was partially supported by KAUST baseline funds and KAUST OSR-CRG2017-3452. ¶ CMAP, École Polytechnique. othmane.mounjid@polytechnique.edu. arXiv:1802.08135v2 [q-fin.TR] 9 Nov 2018 v(t, z) := sup φ∈C(t,z)Remark 3.3. Note that v is bounded from above by 0 by definition. On the other hand, for all E[U (P t,z,0 T , 0, 0, g, i, 0, 0, 0, 0, j)] = e −η(g− j) min i∈[−I * ,I * ] E[U (P t,z,0 T , 0, 0, 0, i, 0, 0, 0, 0, 0)], where P t,z,0 corresponds to the dynamics in the case that the MM does not act on the order book up to T . Moreover, it follows from (3.3) that E[U (P t,z,0 T , 0, 0, 0, i, 0, 0, 0, 0, 0)] ≥ −e ηI * |p b | E[e ηI * (|P t,z,0,b T −p b |+2d+κ) ]where supby Remark 2.1 and the fact that the price can jump only by d when a market event occurs. Thus, v belongs to the class L exp ∞ of functions ϕ such that ϕ/L is bounded, in which The dynamic programming equationThe derivation of the dynamic programming equation is standard, and is based on the dynamic programming principle. We state below the weak version of Bouchard and Touzi [10], we let v * and v * denote the lower-and upper-semicontinuous envelopes of v. Proposition 3.1. Fix (t, z) ∈ [0, T ] × D Z and a family {θ φ , φ ∈ C(t, z)} such that each θ φ is a [t, T ]-valued F t,z,φ -stopping time and Z t,z,φ θ φ L∞ < ∞. Then, sup φ∈C(t,z) E v * (θ φ , Z t,z,φ θ φ ) ≤ v(t, z) ≤ sup φ∈C(t,z)E v * (θ φ , Z t,z,φ θ φ ) .
No abstract
scite is a Brooklyn-based organization that helps researchers better discover and understand research articles through Smart Citations–citations that display the context of the citation and describe whether the article provides supporting or contrasting evidence. scite is used by students and researchers from around the world and is funded in part by the National Science Foundation and the National Institute on Drug Abuse of the National Institutes of Health.
customersupport@researchsolutions.com
10624 S. Eastern Ave., Ste. A-614
Henderson, NV 89052, USA
This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.
Copyright © 2024 scite LLC. All rights reserved.
Made with 💙 for researchers
Part of the Research Solutions Family.