In this laboratory experiment we study the use of strategic ignorance to delegate real authority within a firm. A worker can gather information on investment projects, while a manager makes the implementation decision. The manager can monitor the worker.This allows her to exploit any information gathered by the worker, but also reduces the worker's incentives to gather information in the first place. Both e↵ects are influenced by the interest alignment between manager and worker. Our data confirm the prediction that optimal monitoring depends non-monotonically on the interest alignment between managers and workers. Managers also show some preferences for control that seem to be driven by loss aversion. We also find mild evidence for hidden benefits and costs of control. However, behavioral biases have only limited e↵ects on organizational outcomes. JEL: D20, D40, D63, D82, J30In a variety of strategic situations, more information may hurt an individual. The underlying intuition is that if it is commonly known that an individual gathers more information, this may change the behavior of other individuals. This change in behavior can be detrimental to the better informed individual. Consequently, rational individuals might stay ignorant for strategic reasons. One organizational issue where strategic ignorance is likely to play an important role is the e↵ective delegation of decision rights. This argument is developed in a pioneering contribution by Aghion and Tirole (1997) and explored further in Baker, Gibbons, and Murphy (1999). In Aghion and Tirole a worker fears to be overruled by his manager if the latter is well-informed about the consequences of some operational decisions. This fear thwarts the worker's incentives to gather information. An uninformed manager can credibly commit not to overrule, since she does not know the most appropriate operational decision.Realizing that his preferred decision will be implemented, the worker has stronger incentives to gather information. Strategic ignorance can thus be a crucial tool to delegate e↵ective control over decisions -called real authority -to lower level employees.The argument is compelling from a theoretical point of view, yet empirical evidence on the underlying strategic mechanism is scarce. Moreover, practitioners, the popular business press, and many studies on monetary incentives and control indeed suggest that Aghion and Tirole might ignore important behavioral biases of both managers and workers.Regarding managers, anecdotal evidence paints the picture that many individuals are overly reluctant to delegate decision rights. The negative consequence of such preferences for control are reflected in management advice like Manzoni andBarsoux (1998) andHerzberg (2003).Rather than emphasizing the perils of lost control, this management literature warns for the negative consequences of "micromanagement." The problem of excess centralization has been discussed at least since Williamson (1996, pp.150-151) who comments on the connection between managerial meddling...
It is often assumed that bad corporate performance means a bad CEO. The task of a board of directors is then simple: dismiss the executive. If it fails to do so, the board is said to be indolent. We take a kinder approach to observedWe are grateful to two anonymous referees, a Co-editor, Chaim Fershtman and seminar participants at Erasmus University Rotterdam and the European Public Choice Society Meeting 2005 in Durham for comments. An earlier version of this paper was circulated under the title Disciplining and screening top executives. 1 board behaviour and point to the problems even well-intended boards would encounter. They face the twin task of disciplining and screening executives.We analyse the nature of the retention contract a board uses to discipline and screen executives. Consistent with empirical observation, we …nd that executives may become overly active to show their credentials, and that the link between bad performance and dismissal is weak.
Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. Terms of use: Documents in
scite is a Brooklyn-based organization that helps researchers better discover and understand research articles through Smart Citations–citations that display the context of the citation and describe whether the article provides supporting or contrasting evidence. scite is used by students and researchers from around the world and is funded in part by the National Science Foundation and the National Institute on Drug Abuse of the National Institutes of Health.
customersupport@researchsolutions.com
10624 S. Eastern Ave., Ste. A-614
Henderson, NV 89052, USA
This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.
Copyright © 2024 scite LLC. All rights reserved.
Made with 💙 for researchers
Part of the Research Solutions Family.