This paper introduces the targeted sampling model in optimal auction design. In this model, the seller may specify a quantile interval and sample from a buyer's prior restricted to the interval. This can be interpreted as allowing the seller to, for example, examine the top 40% bids from previous buyers with the same characteristics. The targeting power is quantified with a parameter ∆ ∈ [0, 1] which lower bounds how small the quantile intervals could be. When ∆ = 1, it degenerates to Cole and Roughgarden's model of i.i.d. samples; when it is the idealized case of ∆ = 0, it degenerates to the model studied by Chen et al. [7]. For instance, for n buyers with bounded values in [0, 1], Õ( −1 ) targeted samples suffice while it is known that at least Ω(n −2 ) i.i.d. samples are needed. In other words, targeted sampling with sufficient targeting power allows us to remove the linear dependence in n, and to improve the quadratic dependence in −1 to linear. In this work, we introduce new technical ingredients and show that the number of targeted samples sufficient for learning an -optimal auction is substantially smaller than the sample complexity of i.i.d. samples for the full spectrum of ∆ ∈ [0, 1). Even with only mild targeting power, i.e., whenever ∆ = o(1), our targeted sample complexity upper bounds are strictly smaller than the optimal sample complexity of i.i.d. samples.
This paper introduces the targeted sampling model in optimal auction design. In this model, the seller may specify a quantile interval and sample from a buyer's prior restricted to the interval. This can be interpreted as allowing the seller to, for example, examine the top 40% bids from previous buyers with the same characteristics. The targeting power is quantified with a parameter ∆ ∈ [0, 1] which lower bounds how small the quantile intervals could be. When ∆ = 1, it degenerates to Cole and Roughgarden's model of i.i.d. samples; when it is the idealized case of ∆ = 0, it degenerates to the model studied by Chen et al. [7]. For instance, for n buyers with bounded values in [0, 1],Õ (ϵ −1 ) targeted samples suffice while it is known that at leastΩ(nϵ −2 ) i.i.d. samples are needed. In other words, targeted sampling with sufficient targeting power allows us to remove the linear dependence in n, and to improve the quadratic dependence in ϵ −1 to linear. In this work, we introduce new technical ingredients and show that the number of targeted samples sufficient for learning an ϵ-optimal auction is substantially smaller than the sample complexity of i.i.d. samples for the full spectrum of ∆ ∈ [0, 1). Even with only mild targeting power, i.e., whenever ∆ = o(1), our targeted sample complexity upper bounds are strictly smaller than the optimal sample complexity of i.i.d. samples. CCS Concepts: • Theory of computation → Algorithmic game theory; Algorithmic mechanism design; Convergence and learning in games; Computational pricing and auctions.
scite is a Brooklyn-based organization that helps researchers better discover and understand research articles through Smart Citations–citations that display the context of the citation and describe whether the article provides supporting or contrasting evidence. scite is used by students and researchers from around the world and is funded in part by the National Science Foundation and the National Institute on Drug Abuse of the National Institutes of Health.
customersupport@researchsolutions.com
10624 S. Eastern Ave., Ste. A-614
Henderson, NV 89052, USA
This site is protected by reCAPTCHA and the Google Privacy Policy and Terms of Service apply.
Copyright © 2025 scite LLC. All rights reserved.
Made with 💙 for researchers
Part of the Research Solutions Family.