2002
DOI: 10.1002/bdm.413
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

A re‐examination of probability matching and rational choice

Abstract: In a typical probability learning task participants are presented with a repeated choice between two response alternatives, one of which has a higher payoff probability than the other. Rational choice theory requires that participants should eventually allocate all their responses to the high-payoff alternative, but previous research has found that people fail to maximize their payoffs. Instead, it is commonly observed that people match their response probabilities to the payoff probabilities. We report three … Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1

Citation Types

23
244
1
1

Year Published

2002
2002
2018
2018

Publication Types

Select...
9
1

Relationship

1
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 241 publications
(269 citation statements)
references
References 40 publications
23
244
1
1
Order By: Relevance
“…There was also a marginal interaction between age group and win-stay versus loseshift performance during training (see Figure 3), F(1, 41) ϭ 3.3, p ϭ .078. A potential alternative account of the data is that, rather than showing differences in avoidance learning, perhaps O-O participants are more likely than their Y-O counterparts to optimize, rather than match, responding (e.g., Estes, 1961;Shanks, Tunney, & McCarthy, 2002). Optimizing is characterized by always choosing the stimulus with greatest reward probability, whereas matching reflects a tendency to allocate behavioral choices in proportion to the probabilities.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…There was also a marginal interaction between age group and win-stay versus loseshift performance during training (see Figure 3), F(1, 41) ϭ 3.3, p ϭ .078. A potential alternative account of the data is that, rather than showing differences in avoidance learning, perhaps O-O participants are more likely than their Y-O counterparts to optimize, rather than match, responding (e.g., Estes, 1961;Shanks, Tunney, & McCarthy, 2002). Optimizing is characterized by always choosing the stimulus with greatest reward probability, whereas matching reflects a tendency to allocate behavioral choices in proportion to the probabilities.…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Individually, subjects vary in the amount of optimally choosing the most likely outcome versus nonoptimal behaviors, such as probability matching (see also Shanks et al 2002). In the last two scanning runs, two subjects chose the most likely outcome in 100% of trials, two subjects chose it in at least 94.4% of trials, four subjects chose it in 91.6% of trials, and the other six chose it in a range of 66.6%-88.9% of trials.…”
Section: Behavioral Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“….25 9 .25). Probability matching is highly persistent (Healy and Kubovy 1981;Shanks et al 2002;for reviews, see Myers 1976;Vulkan 2000), even in tasks in which participants did not have to learn the outcome probabilities but were presented with a full description of outcomes and their probability (Gal and Baron 1996;Koehler and James 2009;Newell et al 2013;Newell and Rakow 2007;West and Stanovich 2003).…”
Section: Probability Matching and Its Relation To Betting On Illusorymentioning
confidence: 99%