2017
DOI: 10.1007/s00199-016-1025-9
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Anticipated stochastic choice

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1
1

Citation Types

0
8
0

Year Published

2018
2018
2023
2023

Publication Types

Select...
7

Relationship

0
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 10 publications
(8 citation statements)
references
References 41 publications
0
8
0
Order By: Relevance
“…For instance, researchers have made payments to subjects as a function of judgments involving the relative quantity of dots (Caplin and Dean, 2015;Dutilh and Rieskamp, 2016), the dominant direction of moving dots (Bhui, 2019a;2019b), the number of ‡ickering dots (Oud et al, 2016), a dynamic display of dots (Zeigenfuse, Pleskac, and Liu, 2014), the heights of bars of dynamic size (Tsetsos et al, 2016), and the area occupied by objects of various sizes (Polanía, Krajbich, Grueschow, and Ru¤, 2014). 5 To our knowledge, Du¤y, Gussman, and Smith (2019) is the only other paper that describes a choice experiment where suboptimal choices are perfectly observable because utility Saito, and Tserenjigmid (2018), Koida (2018), Kovach and Tserenjigmid (2018), Caplin, Dean, and Leahy (2019), Cattaneo, Ma, Masatlioglu, and Suleymanov (2019), Conte and Hey (2019), and Natenzon (2019).…”
Section: Choice Involving Imperfectly Perceived Objectsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…For instance, researchers have made payments to subjects as a function of judgments involving the relative quantity of dots (Caplin and Dean, 2015;Dutilh and Rieskamp, 2016), the dominant direction of moving dots (Bhui, 2019a;2019b), the number of ‡ickering dots (Oud et al, 2016), a dynamic display of dots (Zeigenfuse, Pleskac, and Liu, 2014), the heights of bars of dynamic size (Tsetsos et al, 2016), and the area occupied by objects of various sizes (Polanía, Krajbich, Grueschow, and Ru¤, 2014). 5 To our knowledge, Du¤y, Gussman, and Smith (2019) is the only other paper that describes a choice experiment where suboptimal choices are perfectly observable because utility Saito, and Tserenjigmid (2018), Koida (2018), Kovach and Tserenjigmid (2018), Caplin, Dean, and Leahy (2019), Cattaneo, Ma, Masatlioglu, and Suleymanov (2019), Conte and Hey (2019), and Natenzon (2019).…”
Section: Choice Involving Imperfectly Perceived Objectsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Some of the recent choice literature has focused on consideration set e¤ects, whereby 3 A partial list of these e¤orts, not previously mentioned, would include Tversky (1969), Loomes, Starmer, and Sugden (1989), Sopher and Gigliotti (1993), Loomes and Sugden (1995), Sopher and Narramore (2000), Gul and Pesendorfer (2006), Rubinstein and Salant (2006), Tyson (2008), Caplin, Dean, and Martin (2011), Conte, Hey, and Mo¤att (2011), Wilcox (2011), Gul, Natenzon, and Pesendorfer (2014), Loomes and Pogrebna (2014), Woodford (2014), Caplin and Dean (2015), Caplin and Martin (2015), Cubitt, Navarro-Martinez, and Starmer (2015), Lu (2016), Apesteguia, Ballester, and Lu (2017), Dean and Neligh (2017), Ahumada and Ulku (2018), Apesteguia and Ballester (2018), Echenique, Saito, and Tserenjigmid (2018), Koida (2018), Kovach and Tserenjigmid (2018), Caplin, Dean, and Leahy (2019), Conte and Hey (2019), and Natenzon (2019).…”
Section: Related Literaturementioning
confidence: 99%
“…There are also models in the literature that, in contrast to the self-regulation model, can imply a decrease in desire for commitment with mixtures (e.g., Noor and Takeoka [2010] and Masatlioglu, Nakajima, and Ozdenoren [2017]). More broadly, the self-regulation model is also related to a literature on cognitive control of preferences (e.g., Nehring [2006] and Koida [2017]), and to the literature on variational menu choice preferences (e.g., Ergin and Sarver [2010]). We discuss the formal connection with these other models after presenting our axiomatic characterization of the self-regulation model (see Section 6).…”
Section: Self-regulationmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In particular, the overlap of the willpower model in Masatlioglu, Nakajima, and Ozdenoren [2017] with the self-regulation model is the Strotz model, while the overlap of the willpower model in Grant, Hsieh, and Liang [2017] with the self-regulation model is the self-control model. Similar in spirit to the discrete choice model in Nehring [2006], Koida [2017] proposes, using lotteries over menus, a model of internal conflict, where the DM can exercise cognitive control over mental states that trigger ex-post choices. Koida…”
Section: Other Related Modelsmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation