2009
DOI: 10.1007/s00780-008-0085-5
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Asset allocation and liquidity breakdowns: what if your broker does not answer the phone?

Abstract: This paper analyzes the portfolio decision of an investor facing the threat of illiquidity. In a continuous-time setting, the efficiency loss due to illiquidity is addressed and quantified. We show that the efficiency loss for a logarithmic investor with 30 years until the investment horizon is a significant 22.7% of current wealth if the illiquidity part of the model is calibrated to the Japanese data of the aftermath of WW II. Furthermore, it is demonstrated that the threat of illiquidity can change the dema… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
2
1
1

Citation Types

0
15
0

Year Published

2012
2012
2016
2016

Publication Types

Select...
6

Relationship

0
6

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 11 publications
(15 citation statements)
references
References 18 publications
0
15
0
Order By: Relevance
“…(λ 1 , λ 2 ) P 1 (1) P 2 (1) (1,1) 0.257 0.224 (5,5) 0.112 0.103 (10,10) Define W as the space of continuous functions on R + , I the space of cadlag I d -valued functions, N the space of nondecreasing cadlag N-valued functions. On W × I × N , define the filtration (B 0 t ) t≥0 , where B 0 t is the smallest σ-algebra making the coordinate mappings for s ≤ t measurable, and define B 0 t+ = s>t B 0 s .…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…(λ 1 , λ 2 ) P 1 (1) P 2 (1) (1,1) 0.257 0.224 (5,5) 0.112 0.103 (10,10) Define W as the space of continuous functions on R + , I the space of cadlag I d -valued functions, N the space of nondecreasing cadlag N-valued functions. On W × I × N , define the filtration (B 0 t ) t≥0 , where B 0 t is the smallest σ-algebra making the coordinate mappings for s ≤ t measurable, and define B 0 t+ = s>t B 0 s .…”
Section: Discussionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…First, we extend the papers [19] and [15] by considering stochastic intensity trading times and regime switching in the asset prices. For a two-state Markov chain modulating the market liquidity, and in the limiting case where the intensity in one regime goes to infinity, while the other one goes to zero, we recover the setup of [5] and [14] where an investor can trade continuously in the perfectly liquid regime but faces a threat of trading interruptions during a period of market freeze. On the other hand, regime switching models in optimal investment problems was already used in [23], [20] or [21] for continuous-time trading.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 89%
“…Remark 2.1. More generally (see [5,17]) the market need not be static during the illiquid periods. Thus, one may postulate modified dynamics for the stock during the liquidity shock and also include instantaneous price drops when the liquidity regime changes.…”
Section: The Market Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In recent years a number of approaches for dealing with market illiquidity within optimal investment frameworks have been developed. Schwartz and Tebaldi [21] considered the optimal portfolio problem with permanent trading interruptions; Diesinger et al [5] addressed terminal wealth maximization for CRRA utilities. Ludkovski and Min [17] and Gassiat et al [9] analyzed the impact of illiquidity on optimal consumption strategies.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Related Literature There are large strands of literature concerning both regime‐shift models on the one hand and large investor models on the other. Models with possible regime shifts related to optimal investment problems include the articles of BR, Sass and Haussmann (2004), Diesinger, Kraft, and Seifried (2010), or Kashiwabara and Nakamura (2011), among others; see also the monograph of Elliott, Aggoun, and Moore (1994).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%