2006
DOI: 10.2139/ssrn.988642
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Can Risk Aversion Explain Schooling Attainments? Evidence from Italy

Abstract: Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1

Citation Types

5
80
0
2

Year Published

2008
2008
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
7
1

Relationship

1
7

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 66 publications
(87 citation statements)
references
References 44 publications
5
80
0
2
Order By: Relevance
“…Using unique Italian panel data (the Bank of Italy Survey of Income and Wealth) in which individual differences in attitudes toward risk are measurable, we develop a nonrational expectation econometric model of sequential schooling decisions. 3 We infer the subjective effect of continuing to a higher grade level on marginal risk exposure, from the estimated effect of risk aversion on the decision to attend higher education. We take into account the potential endogeneity of risk aversion.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…Using unique Italian panel data (the Bank of Italy Survey of Income and Wealth) in which individual differences in attitudes toward risk are measurable, we develop a nonrational expectation econometric model of sequential schooling decisions. 3 We infer the subjective effect of continuing to a higher grade level on marginal risk exposure, from the estimated effect of risk aversion on the decision to attend higher education. We take into account the potential endogeneity of risk aversion.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This would be difficult to achieve and indeed, as of now, such a comprehensive study does not exist. 3 Because we do not model how subjective distributions are inferred, the model is not necessarily inconsistent with a standard rational expectation framework. However, we use the term non-rational expectations in order to differentiate our approach from the structural dynamic expected utility models, in which Bellman equations are solved explicitly, for a given set of beliefs.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…However, there is no general consensus on the direction of such differences: some studies find a negative relationship between education and risk aversion (Weiss 1972;Belzil and Leonardi 2006;Ferrer-i-Carbonell 2005;Binswanger 1980Binswanger , 1981Guiso and Paiella 2001;and Andersen et al 2005), while Barsky et al (1997) find an inverse U-shaped relationship, with risk tolerance peaking at 12 years of education. There are some consistent patterns of a negative relationship between unemployment duration and risk aversion, (see Feinberg 1977, andKohn andSchooler 1978).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…2 In line with these findings is the idea of introducing risk and other non-pecuniary elements in the empirical model. 3 Further, Heckman, Lochner, and Todd (2006) give reasons why option values should be included in the decision, and show how option values invalidate the internal rate of return as an investment choice criterion.…”
Section: Introductionmentioning
confidence: 82%
“…Proposition 1 For a constant accumulation of costs per year of successful schooling (1), a sequence of increasing earning levels through schooling described by (2), and an earning dynamics after market entry following (3) we can determine the threshold Y * (T ) that would trigger the start of the earning/working process.…”
Section: Entry Thresholdmentioning
confidence: 99%