2014
DOI: 10.1257/mac.6.1.162
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Can Tax Rebates Stimulate Consumption Spending in a Life-Cycle Model?

Abstract: We build a life-cycle model with earnings risk, liquidity constraints, and portfolio choice over tax-deferred and taxable assets to evaluate how household consumption changes in response to shocks to transitory anticipated income, such as the 2001 income tax rebate. Households optimally invest in tax-deferred assets, which are encumbered by withdrawal penalties, and exchange taxable precautionary savings for higher after-tax returns. The model predicts a higher marginal propensity to consume out of a rebate th… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1

Citation Types

3
23
0

Year Published

2014
2014
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
8
1

Relationship

1
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 21 publications
(27 citation statements)
references
References 54 publications
3
23
0
Order By: Relevance
“…The tax rebate of 2001 was part of a broader tax reform, the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (EGTRRA), enacted in May 2001 by the U.S. Congress. Huntley and Michelangeli's (2014) model focused exclusively on the distinction between taxable and tax-deferred assets. In order to make this component of the reform highly visible during calendar year 2001, the Administration paid 11 For example, within incomplete-markets economies, Aiyagari and Gertler (1991) focused on the equity premium; Erosa and Ventura (2002) revisited, quantitatively, the question of welfare effects of inflation; Ragot (2011) studied the joint distribution of money and financial assets.…”
Section: On the 2001 Tax Rebatementioning
confidence: 99%
“…The tax rebate of 2001 was part of a broader tax reform, the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act (EGTRRA), enacted in May 2001 by the U.S. Congress. Huntley and Michelangeli's (2014) model focused exclusively on the distinction between taxable and tax-deferred assets. In order to make this component of the reform highly visible during calendar year 2001, the Administration paid 11 For example, within incomplete-markets economies, Aiyagari and Gertler (1991) focused on the equity premium; Erosa and Ventura (2002) revisited, quantitatively, the question of welfare effects of inflation; Ragot (2011) studied the joint distribution of money and financial assets.…”
Section: On the 2001 Tax Rebatementioning
confidence: 99%
“…A number of important macroeconomic implications of heterogeneous responses to shocks and stabilization policies have been recently investigated in the theoretical literature (Ragot 2010, Kaplan andViolante forthcoming, andHuntley andMichelangeli 2014). Yet, their relevance towards measuring the impact of fiscal policy on aggregate expenditure has been overlooked in the data.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Finally, some work (van den Noord, 2000;Barrell and Pina, 2004;Veld, Larch, and Vandeweyer, 2013) uses large macro simulation models to conduct exercises in the same spirit as ours, but their models are often too complicated to isolate the different channels of stabilization and they typically assume representative agents, shutting off the redistribution and social insurance channels that we will find to be important. Huntley and Michelangeli (2011) and Kaplan and Violante (2014) are closer to us in the use of optimizing models with heterogeneous agents to study fiscal policy. However, they estimate multipliers to discretionary tax rebates, whereas we estimate the systematic impact on the ergodic variance of the automatic features of the fiscal code.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%