2009
DOI: 10.1038/sj.bjc.6605288
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Cancer phenotype as the outcome of an evolutionary game between normal and malignant cells

Abstract: BACKGROUND: There is variability in the cancer phenotype across individuals: two patients with the same tumour may experience different disease life histories, resulting from genetic variation within the tumour and from the interaction between tumour and host. Until now, phenotypic variability has precluded a clear-cut identification of the fundamental characteristics of a given tumour type. METHODS: Using multiple myeloma as an example, we apply the principles of evolutionary game theory to determine the fund… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

3
110
1
1

Year Published

2013
2013
2020
2020

Publication Types

Select...
7
2

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 107 publications
(115 citation statements)
references
References 44 publications
3
110
1
1
Order By: Relevance
“…Tomlinson [1997] and Tomlinson & Bodmer [1997] used the hawk-dove game, to explain why game theory can be used to understand conflict and cooperation between cancer cells; subsequent papers [Bach et al 2001, Dingli et al 2009, Basanta et al 2008a,b, 2011, 2012, Gerstung et al 2011 have extended that model to up to 4 strategies. 2-player games, however, are not appropriate to study collective interactions and can lead to misunderstandings [Archetti & Scheuring 2012].…”
Section: Further Developments Of the Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Tomlinson [1997] and Tomlinson & Bodmer [1997] used the hawk-dove game, to explain why game theory can be used to understand conflict and cooperation between cancer cells; subsequent papers [Bach et al 2001, Dingli et al 2009, Basanta et al 2008a,b, 2011, 2012, Gerstung et al 2011 have extended that model to up to 4 strategies. 2-player games, however, are not appropriate to study collective interactions and can lead to misunderstandings [Archetti & Scheuring 2012].…”
Section: Further Developments Of the Modelmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…At the other extreme of biological organization, endogenous pathogen cells produce metabolites that represent a public good, e.g., during cancer progression (17); treating cancer progression as a game between normal and malignant cells is thus natural (18,19) and was already suggested nearly a decade ago by Axelrod et al (20). Cancer itself of course represents a breakdown in cooperation and the maintenance of a public good (21), so the idea of developing new strategies for treating cancer-e.g., by attacking the public goods that allow cancers to thrive-seems an appropriate turnabout (17,22,23).…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Such a coexistence between MM and OC (figure 5c) will prevail even if d ¼ 0 (MM and OB are neutral with respect to each other). However, changes in d may have a significant impact on the life history of the disease and associated progression time [47].…”
Section: Resultsmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Let us denote by x i (t), the relative frequencies of the cell types: x 1 (t) (OC cells), x 2 (t) (OB cells) and x 3 (t) (MM cells The benefits and costs resulting from the interacting cell populations are captured in the initial pay-off matrix (1.2), here associated with matrix A ij . We may reduce this matrix to the minimal pay-off matrix (4.3) by taking into account that the nature of the fixed points of the evolutionary dynamics (though not their location) remains unaffected under a projective transformation of the relative cells frequencies [10], leading to [47] b ¼ c/e and d ¼ dc/be. Note further, that the REs and associated dynamics remain unaffected if we add an arbitrary constant to each column of the pay-off matrix.…”
Section: Appendix Amentioning
confidence: 99%