2000
DOI: 10.1016/s1574-0056(00)80005-6
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Chapter 2 Measurement of inequality

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
1
1
1
1

Citation Types

1
279
0
8

Year Published

2003
2003
2019
2019

Publication Types

Select...
4
3
2

Relationship

0
9

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 481 publications
(288 citation statements)
references
References 259 publications
1
279
0
8
Order By: Relevance
“…This axiom, sometimes also called 'symmetry', requires that the underlying social welfare function uses only the information about the income variable and not about, for example, some other characteristics which might be discernible in a sample or an enumeration of the population (Cowell 2000). This assumption is usually invoked for welfare orderings, whether we look at inequality (Atkinson 1970) or at poverty (Greer, Foster and Thorbecke 1984).…”
Section: The Anonymity Axiommentioning
confidence: 99%
“…This axiom, sometimes also called 'symmetry', requires that the underlying social welfare function uses only the information about the income variable and not about, for example, some other characteristics which might be discernible in a sample or an enumeration of the population (Cowell 2000). This assumption is usually invoked for welfare orderings, whether we look at inequality (Atkinson 1970) or at poverty (Greer, Foster and Thorbecke 1984).…”
Section: The Anonymity Axiommentioning
confidence: 99%
“…A first conclusion is that between-country inequality variation is more significant 1 A comprehensive survey of the topic can be found in Cowell (2000).…”
Section: Overviewmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…It is known that for values above one, the Atkinson index is very sensitive to abnormally low incomes (Cowell, 1995). With this in mind, we estimate the four values to have a broader picture of how θ affects the levels and trends of inequality.…”
Section: Inequality Measurementmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…In the case of scale-invariant distributional measures (see Cowell, 2000) and linearly homogenous tax-benefit systems, the decomposition of other effects (equations [4][5][8][9] simplifies because the effect of a change in nominal levels becomes (approximately) zero at the population level. 14 Furthermore, equation 4 is now equivalent to 5 and equation 8 is equivalent to equation 9, reducing the overall number of combinations from four to two.…”
Section: Decomposing Static Policy Effectsmentioning
confidence: 99%