2004
DOI: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2003.06.005
|View full text |Cite
|
Sign up to set email alerts
|

Consumption and risk sharing over the life cycle

Abstract: A striking feature of U.S. data on income and consumption is that inequality increases with age. This paper asks if individual-specific earnings risk can provide a coherent explanation. We find that it can. We construct an overlapping generations general equilibrium model in which households face uninsurable earnings shocks over the course of their lifetimes. Earnings inequality is exogenous and is calibrated to match data from the U.S. Panel Study on Income Dynamics. Consumption inequality is endogenous and m… Show more

Help me understand this report

Search citation statements

Order By: Relevance

Paper Sections

Select...
3
1

Citation Types

18
357
3
7

Year Published

2007
2007
2024
2024

Publication Types

Select...
6
2

Relationship

0
8

Authors

Journals

citations
Cited by 531 publications
(385 citation statements)
references
References 32 publications
18
357
3
7
Order By: Relevance
“…In particular, the two-state Markov chain is calibrated so that the annual persistence amounts to 0.98 with an implied conditional variance of 8%. Accordingly, {η 1 , η 2 } = {0.727, 1.273} and Our modeling of individual productivity is in accordance with the large-scale OLG models of Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (2004), Conesa and Krueger (1999), and Krueger and Ludwig (2007). We acknowledge that our specification of the individual productivity process and, hence, the labor earnings is rather parsimonious and a simplification with respect to recent empirical evidence.…”
Section: Individual Productivitysupporting
confidence: 61%
See 2 more Smart Citations
“…In particular, the two-state Markov chain is calibrated so that the annual persistence amounts to 0.98 with an implied conditional variance of 8%. Accordingly, {η 1 , η 2 } = {0.727, 1.273} and Our modeling of individual productivity is in accordance with the large-scale OLG models of Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (2004), Conesa and Krueger (1999), and Krueger and Ludwig (2007). We acknowledge that our specification of the individual productivity process and, hence, the labor earnings is rather parsimonious and a simplification with respect to recent empirical evidence.…”
Section: Individual Productivitysupporting
confidence: 61%
“…The age-efficiency profile {̄} 45 =1 is taken from Hansen (1993), interpolated to in-between years and normalized to one. The set of the equally distributed productivity types{ϵ 1 , ϵ 2 } = {0.57, 1.43} is taken from Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (2004). Our choice of the stochastic individual productivity component, η ∈ {η 1 , η 2 }, is also motivated by Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (2004).…”
Section: Individual Productivitymentioning
confidence: 99%
See 1 more Smart Citation
“…The …rst speci…cation follows Aiyagari (1994) and sets = 0:60 and 2 " = 0:013, while the second follows Hubbard et al (1995, HSZ) and sets = 0:95 and 2 " = 0:030. The …nal speci…cation, suggested by Storesletten et al (2000), is even more persistent and sets = 0:98 and 2 " = 0:020. In addition to examining these processes, I also examine the methods'accuracy for a broader set of autocorrelations.…”
Section: The Problemmentioning
confidence: 99%
“…Among many other studies in the quantitative life-cycle literature, this paper is closely related to Guvenen (2007), Storesletten et al (2004), and Karahan and Ozkan (2010). Those papers study the role of income processes on the age-inequality profile of consumption.…”
mentioning
confidence: 99%